Fed Pressed on Questions of Diversity
Fed Pressed on Questions of Diversity
The Federal Reserve faces criticism from lawmakers and others over its record on diversity at the same time the central...
The Federal Reserve faces criticism from lawmakers and others over its record on diversity at the same time the central bank is highlighting the economic outlook for minority groups.
Several Democrats on the Senate Banking Committee questioned Fed Chairwoman Janet Yellen on Tuesday about the selection process for regional Fed bank presidents, echoing the concerns of advocacy groups who have said the system should be more open and allow more public input.
The 12 regional bank presidents are appointed by regional boards, subject to approval by the Washington, D.C.-based Fed board of governors. As heads of regional Fed branches, they are expected to keep their fingers on the pulse of their local economies and participate on decisions about interest rates. Just two of the current presidents are women and none are black or Hispanic. The last black president stepped down in 1974.
Sen. Elizabeth Warren (D., Mass.) criticized the selection process, saying Washington officials represented little more than a rubber stamp. Earlier this year, Fed governors signed off on the reappointment of most bank presidents until 2021 “without any public debate or any public discussion,” she said.
“If you’re concerned about this, why didn’t you use either of these opportunities to say enough is enough. Let’s go back and see if we can find qualified regional presidents who also contribute to the overall diversity of the Fed’s leadership?” Ms. Warren asked.
“It just shows me that the selection process for regional Fed presidents is broken,” retorted Ms. Warren, calling on Congress to consider changing the process.
The Center for Popular Democracy, a left-leaning advocacy group, has been pressing the Fed for months to increase the diversity of its leadership, as have many Democrats on Capitol Hill who signed onto a letter from Ms. Warren to Ms. Yellen on the matter last month.
Presumptive Democratic presidential nominee Hillary Clinton has also weighed in. Her campaign released a statement saying the Fed “needs to be more representative of America as a whole.”
In a June 13 response to the lawmakers’ letter, Ms. Yellen acknowledged “there is still work to be done” on diversity within the Fed ranks “and I assure you that workforce diversity remains a priority for the Federal Reserve.”
In her prepared testimony Tuesday, Ms. Yellen stressed the need to ensure that the gains from the economic recovery are widely distributed.
She noted that blacks and Hispanics are still suffering some of the effects of the recession in more pronounced ways than other groups. Black and Hispanic workers still face higher unemployment rates than the workforce as a whole, she said.
“It is troubling that unemployment rates for these minority groups remain higher than for the nation overall, and that the annual income of the median African-American household is still well below the median income of other U.S. households,” Ms. Yellen said.
Diverging economic circumstances between white and black households predate the recession but the gaps widened after the financial crisis and have only barely narrowed in the recovery.
A Fed report released alongside Ms. Yellen’s testimony found that black households, which saw their median incomes fall 16% during the recession, are only 88% of the way back to prerecession levels. White households, by contrast, saw incomes fall only 8% and are already back to 94% of prerecession levels, the report said.
It is rare for the Fed to address the economic conditions for individual demographic groups. The central bank’s congressional mandate requires that it seek to hold down unemployment and keep inflation stable for the country as a whole. In the past, Ms. Yellen has said she was sympathetic to the economic troubles of minority groups but stressed the Fed’s options for addressing them were limited.
Ms. Yellen’s comments Tuesday suggest a rising recognition within the Fed that the racial gaps in the economy are becoming more pronounced and that there is a role for monetary policy to play in shrinking those gaps.
“It’s important for us to be aware of those differences and to focus on them as we think about monetary policy and work that the Federal Reserve does in the area of community development,” she said.
Ms. Yellen is set to address the House Financial Services Committee on Wednesday and could face many of the same questions.
By David Harrison
Source
Report: $15 Chicago Minimum Wage Would Lift Up Struggling Workers
Progress Illinois - May 27, 2014, by Ellyn Fortino - A proposal to hike Chicago's minimum wage to $15 an hour would not...
Progress Illinois - May 27, 2014, by Ellyn Fortino - A proposal to hike Chicago's minimum wage to $15 an hour would not only be a boon for many low-wage workers but also the city's economy, according to a new report by the Center for Popular Democracy.
"Raising the minimum wage to $15 an hour would promote economic stability among Chicago workers, economic vitality in their neighborhoods and economic growth throughout this city," said Connie Razza, director of strategic research at the center, which works both locally and nationally to build "the strength and capacity of democratic organizations to envision and advance a pro-worker, pro-immigrant, racial and economic justice agenda."
The new report comes ahead of Wednesday's Chicago City Council meeting, during which aldermen with the Progressive Reform Caucus plan to introduce an ordinance for a citywide hourly minimum wage of $15 an hour. The ordinance was developed with members of Raise Chicago, a coalition of community and labor groups advocating for a higher hourly wage floor in the city. Chicago's current minimum wage is $8.25 an hour, the same as the base hourly wage in Illinois and $1 more than the federal level.
Under the proposed ordinance, large companies in Chicago making at least $50 million annually would have one year to phase in a $15 minimum hourly wage, including for workers at their subsidiaries and franchise locations, according to Raise Chicago. Small and mid-sized businesses would have slightly more than five years to boost their employees' wages to $15 an hour.
The first phase of the proposed ordinance, which would apply to larger firms, would increase the wages for 22 percent of Chicago workers, or 229,000 people, according to the report. Phase one would generate nearly $1.5 billion in new gross wages annually, or $1.1 billion after deductions. During the first stage of the proposed ordinance, the higher employee wages would mean an estimated $616 million in new economic activity across the region, leading to the creation of 5,350 new jobs, the report showed. A $15 hourly wage for workers employed by large businesses in the city would also provide approximately $45 million in new sales tax revenue.
Increased wages for workers could also lower employee turnover costs for businesses, according to the report. Requiring Chicago employers with annual gross revenues of $50 million or greater to pay their workers at least $15 an hour would reduce labor turnover in the workforce by as much as 80 percent per year.
However, larger firms covered under the proposed ordinance could see their overall employer costs increase by up to 4 percent, according to the report's estimations. As a result, affected firms may raise consumer prices by about 2 percent. Such a price hike would translate into an $0.08 increase for a $4 hamburger, the report noted.
Ald. Roderick Sawyer (6th), who intends to co-sponsor the ordinance, said he expects about 10 out of the 50 Chicago aldermen to initially sign on to the legislation.
"The push then would be to get others to join with us in this cause, because it's important," the alderman said. "We should have talked about this many, many years ago, and had (the minimum wage) kept up with inflation, we might not be having this conversation right now. ... I'm hoping that our colleagues will see that this is not a job killer."
Sawyer said there is no specific date planned for when the proposal could go up for a full city council vote.
It is the alderman's hope that Chicago Mayor Rahm Emanuel's recently-formed minimum wage task force will consider the $15 minimum wage proposal. Emanuel has asked members on the diverse committee, chaired by Ald. Will Burns (4th) and the Sargent Shriver National Center on Poverty Law's President John Bouman, to craft a plan to increase the wages for hourly minimum wage and tipped workers in the city.
"I understand the interest in forming this committee," Sawyer said. "I don't think it's necessary because a proposed ordinance is ready to be submitted tomorrow. But now that the committee has been talked about, this [$15 minimum wage ordinance] is the first thing they can look at."
Sawyer and other backers of a $15 minimum wage are "open to listening to any and all suggestions" about the proposed ordinance, the alderman said. Sawyer also noted that Chicagoans are in favor of a $15 minimum wage.
During the March primary election, Chicago voters overwhelming supported a non-binding ballot referendum to increase the city's minimum wage to $15 an hour for employees of companies with annual revenues over $50 million. The referendum appeared on the ballot in 103 city precincts, garnering support from 87 percent of voters.
Katelyn Johnson, executive director of Action Now, which is involved with the Raise Chicago campaign, said the city's strong public support of a $15 minimum wage is not surprising.
"We know that people in this city are struggling," she stressed. "The current minimum wage in Illinois is only $8.25 an hour, and that's so low that the workers, and certainly those who are supporting families, simply cannot survive, oftentimes working two or three jobs just to make ends meet and make other major personal sacrifices for themselves and their families.
"The $15 an hour wage will correct that," Johnson added. "It will provide a path out of poverty for families and allow (workers) to meet their families' basic needs so they no longer have to rely on food stamps or other public assistance. And in addition, it will stimulate the city's economy."
A total of 900,000 people work in Chicago, and 329,000 of them make less than $15 an hour, according to the report. Blacks and Latinos are disproportionately represented among low-wage workers in the city.
Blacks and Latinos make up 23.6 percent and 26.8 percent of the share of all Chicago workers, respectively. However, 28 percent of low-wage earners in the city are black and 42.4 percent are Latino. Low-wage workers who live in the city are concentrated in the Chicago neighborhoods of Austin, Avondale, Bridgeport and McKinley Park, among other areas.
"This geographic concentration of residents earning low wages means that an increase in the minimum wage will offer larger benefits to certain neighborhoods, while also stimulating the citywide economy," the report reads.
Meanwhile, Chicago aldermen are up for re-election next year, and Sawyer said those who co-sponsor the $15 minimum wage ordinance might see more support from voters at the polls.
"I think in my community, (supporting a $15 an hour minimum wage) plays better. People that try to live off of minimum wage understand that it needs to be raised, so those [aldermen] that have people that can understand that will obviously fare better," Sawyer said. "Maybe some in more affluent wards, it many not play as well, but even those there can understand the economic impact."
People who "have more disposable income, they spend it," the alderman continued. "And if you have more disposable income and you spend it, that means the money is circulating in those individual communities. Sales taxes are paid. That means we can get more revenue to do things: Pay down debt, infrastructure improvements, capital improvements."
Over the next few months, Raise Chicago members and others plan to take part in a number of activities to build community support for a $15 Chicago minimum wage and "put pressure on elected officials to carry out the will of the people," Johnson said.
When asked if Chicagoans can expect to see more public protests concerning the minimum wage, Johnson said, "We'll see."
Be sure to check back with Progress Illinois for our coverage of Wednesday's Chicago City Council meeting.
Source
38 Triangle area leaders now urge ‘No’ vote on all 6 constitutional amendments
38 Triangle area leaders now urge ‘No’ vote on all 6 constitutional amendments
More than three dozen Triangle area mayors and council members now publicly oppose six constitutional amendments on the...
More than three dozen Triangle area mayors and council members now publicly oppose six constitutional amendments on the ballot Nov. 6. Thirty-eight leaders from Apex, Carrboro, Chapel Hill, Durham, Garner, Hillsborough, Holly Springs, Morrisville, Raleigh, Chatham County, Orange County and Wake County governments have signed a letter criticizing the amendments’ “potentially damaging impact.” The letter was released Thursday by Local Progress and Common Cause NC.”
Read the full article here.
New York dedicates millions of dollars to help immigrants fight deportations
New York dedicates millions of dollars to help immigrants fight deportations
New York will soon offer free legal services for poor immigrants facing deportations, thanks to a new budget provision...
New York will soon offer free legal services for poor immigrants facing deportations, thanks to a new budget provision announced this week by Gov. Andrew Cuomo.
The state’s 2017-2018 budget sets aside $10 million for expanding immigrant legal defense services, $4 million of which will go to the Vera Institute of Justice’s New York Immigrant Family Unity Project — a coalition of groups that seek to ensure that all undocumented immigrants have public defenders...
Read full article here.
Former Yellen Adviser Proposes Sweeping Reform of Fed System
Former Yellen Adviser Proposes Sweeping Reform of Fed System
A former aide to Federal Reserve Chair Janet Yellen has broken ranks with his former employer and issued a blueprint...
A former aide to Federal Reserve Chair Janet Yellen has broken ranks with his former employer and issued a blueprint for a sweeping reform of the U.S. central bank, including regular government audits and shorter term limits for policy makers.
Dartmouth College professor Andrew Levin targeted four areas of change for the Federal Reserve system: make the Fed a fully public institution; ensure the process of picking regional Fed presidents is transparent; set seven-year term limits for regional presidents and Board governors; and make the entire Fed subject to external review.
The proposals were taken up by the union-backed activist group Fed Up, which promoted them Monday in a conference call with journalists, and come during an election year where the central bank has been a campaign topic.
“There is one key principle in this document which is the Fed needs to become a public institution,” Levin said. “Pragmatic, reasonable Fed reform should be able to be passed by the Congress, by both parties. That is my hope.”
The Dartmouth professor worked two decades at the Fed, and was a special adviser from 2010 to 2012 to former chairman Ben S. Bernanke, and Yellen when she was vice chair, according to his biography page at the university.
Legislative Plans
Republicans in the U.S. Senate and the House of Representatives last year proposed legislation that included reforms of the central bank, though none has become law. Fed spokeswoman Michelle Smith declined to comment.
As recently as February, Yellen said that while the Fed might be structured differently if it were created today, she believed it still worked well and wasn’t “broken.”
“Of course the structure could be something different and it’s up to Congress to decide that -- I certainly respect that,” she said at a Senate hearing. “I simply mean to say I don’t think it’s broken the way it is.”
The Fed system, which sets interest rates for the U.S. economy, is made up of a Board of Governors in Washington and 12 regional Fed banks. It was created by an act of Congress, yet private banks hold stock in the regional Fed institutions as a result of the way the capital structure was set up when the Fed was born more than a century ago.
“The Federal Reserve is the only central bank that I know of that isn’t a fully public central bank,” Levin said in an interview.
Levin said the 12 regional banks should become fully public entities, meaning they have to somehow eliminate or repurchase the stock they have issued to private member banks. He also proposed banning anyone affiliated with financial institutions overseen by the Fed from serving as a regional Fed director.
Three Classes
Each regional Fed has a nine-member board of directors which includes three Class A directors who represent private member banks, three Class B directors picked by the private banks to represent the public -- typically local business people -- and three Class C directors chosen to represent the public by the Fed board in Washington.
The presence of financial interests on Fed boards has been a long-standing source of criticism. Currently, for example, James Gorman, chairman and chief executive of Morgan Stanley, sits on the New York Fed Board as a Class A director.
Prior the passage of the Dodd-Frank financial reform act in 2010, Class A directors also helped pick the 12 regional Fed bank presidents, subject to the approval of the board in Washington. That potential conflict of interest, with bankers appointing their own supervisors, was limited by Dodd-Frank, which restricted the selection process to Class B and Class C directors.
Levin said the current system of picking Fed presidents, which is led by regional board directors, is too secretive. He recommended the reserve bank boards accept nominations from the public, publish a list of eligible nominees, and then engage in a “selection process that involves genuine public participation.”
The Dartmouth professor also said that the entire Fed system should be subject to “external reviews” and disclosure requirements “just like every other key public agency.”
“The Government Accountability Office should produce a regular annual review of all aspects of the Fed’s policies, procedures, management, and operations,” Levin wrote in his proposal. The Fed has strenuously objected to calls by Republican lawmakers that monetary policy decisions be subject to GAO audit. In the interview, Levin said the GAO should focus on the management and operations of the Fed system, “not so much on monetary policy.”
“Part of the financial crisis was due to mismanagement in the division of supervision at the Fed,” Levin said in an interview. GAO reviews would provide assurance to the public and Congress that the “Fed is a well-managed organization,” he said.
By Craig Torres
Source
Transcript: WSJ Interview With Philadelphia Fed’s Patrick Harker
Transcript: WSJ Interview With Philadelphia Fed’s Patrick Harker
Patrick T. Harker, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, sat down for an interview with The Wall...
Patrick T. Harker, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, sat down for an interview with The Wall Street Journal’s Michael S. Derby on Thursday, Oct. 13, 2016. Here is a transcript of the exchange, lightly edited for length and clarity.
MICHAEL S. DERBY: So we already talked about a lot of the economic and monetary policy stuff. And we just met, so I’m not going to keep getting you to say the same things over and over again. And since I knew this – we were going to be talking after, you know, the speech – I thought we might sort of take a step back and think about, you know, you’ve been in the job a year and a – I mean, a little over a year now.
And, you know, you come to the position from a different background than some other central bankers do. I mean, there’s a lot of economists and research directors who’ve come up, or people from the financial sector. And so I figure I’d start off by asking you just your sense of, you know, like how it’s been, you know, coming in, and what kind of things you’ve learned about the job, and the challenges you’ve faced so far as you, you know, come to lead this institution.
You know, a little bit about my background. While I have degrees in engineering, I also have a degree in economics. I’m published a lot in spatial economics, so micro/spatial economics, what are called Takayama-Judge models or all-trade models. So – (laughs) – yeah. And then – and in addition to that, I’m a quant. So it’s not as though I came to the job with no understanding of the economics that underlie what we do. So let me start with that.
It’s been a really great first – little over first year for a couple of reasons. One, this role is not only important at the national level with respect to monetary policy, which is always the headline event for the Fed and the (Federal Open Market Committee), but I really enjoy the work we’re doing at the regional level, and really trying to create a better environment for job creation and economic mobility and inclusiveness for the economy here. You know, and Philadelphia, the Third District, is uniquely challenged given that we are the poorest top 10 city in America. We have communities throughout our district that are struggling. And so I think the Fed, through our research capability, our ability to convene people, we can have meaningful conversations about that and really start to create more and more opportunity. That’s why we launched this Agenda for Poverty and Prosperity, right?
So we’ve got a challenge here. I think that challenge is also national, but we have it uniquely here in Philadelphia, in the region. And even despite the fact that Philadelphia as a city itself is doing quite well, we need to start bringing more people into the economy productively, first and foremost for those people, but also for the economy. I mean, as I discussed in the speech just prior to this, we need more people in the workforce. And so immigration may be part of that solution, but a substantial component of that, just you look at the numbers, are bringing more people – unskilled people into job-training programs and workforce-development programs to get the jobs they need, and then have those jobs for them, and that they’re able to live somewhere near those jobs, right? It’s no good to have the jobs and have the skills and not be able to get to the job, right? So I think it’s a three-legged stool that we’re trying to develop here.
You know, and that’s – this is a – the other thing, to answer your specific question, is this is an incredible team of people. I mean, I’ve been really – I got to know them a little bit when I was director here, but you only get to meet certain people, right? Now I’ve been out and about in the Bank and in the community and see what we do, and, boy, it’s really impressive what the Philly Fed does. And I think you multiply that across the system.
MR. DERBY: What have you been doing to – I mean, if you come – like, as you say, you do have the M.A. in economics and you’ve done – you’ve done work in that area. But, like, as you’ve been – and you were director, obviously.
MR. HARKER: Yes.
MR. DERBY: So you weren’t unattached to what the institution was doing. But your predecessors – say Charles Plosser, I mean, he had some very strong views on monetary policy and the economy.
MR. HARKER: Yeah. Yeah, yeah.
MR. DERBY: And what have you been doing to come into your own on that front?
MR. HARKER: So I tend to be more of a pragmatist. And first you start with a little bit of humility on what we really know and the state of theory and practice when it comes to macroeconomics. Despite a lot of advances – and we’ve made a lot of advances in the field – there’s still a lot of things we don’t know, I mean, at a fairly fundamental level, right? I mean, we still debate questions on measuring inflation and inflation dynamics, measuring GDP and GDP – what’s happening with productivity. So you come into this understanding that while we have a deep bench of theorists and empiricists that need to inform policy, at the end of the day you need to base your judgment not on an ideology, but on the facts on the ground, right, as best we know them. And I think that’s what I bring to the table.
And then part of that is, you know, engineers are inherently pragmatic by nature. You know, the old engineering joke, the optimist says the glass is half-full, the pessimist says it’s half-empty, the engineer says you’ve got twice as much glass as you need there. (Laughter.)
MR. DERBY: I haven’t heard that joke, but yeah, that’s a good one.
MR. HARKER: So I think – and it’s part of, I think, the portfolio of talent that the Fed has attracted. You don’t want everybody to have the same background. You don’t want everybody to have the same life experiences. So you need some people in the room who have come from different experiences. You need some people in the room, I believe, who have actually worked on the other side of the financial markets – actually participating in the financial markets, not just regulating them, right, and theorizing about them. So I think you need – it’s the mix that makes for the richness of the conversation that happens in the room.
MR. DERBY: Has the Fed been too dominated by academics, and especially academic economists? Because that’s been one of the criticisms the Fed has faced at various points over the years.
MR. HARKER: So that’s an interesting question because I think that the Fed has – over time it cycles. You need some base knowledge of economic theory to be able to meaningfully participate in the conversation, but you can get that in different ways, right? You also, I think, need some understanding of markets and market functioning, right? And you can learn that, but it’s better if you’ve had some of that experience. And lastly, I think you need in the room – not everybody brings – you know, not everybody has all three of these things I’m saying at once, right, but it’s the mix of people. You need people with practical industry experience. And again, you can either get that by having run large institutions, for-profit, nonprofit; being on corporate boards, so they get some sense of how that decision process – that all has to be in the mix. But at the base we still need those economists, right, because ultimately we are dominated by, you could say – but really for a good reason – that base of economic talent because that’s the business we’re in.
MR. DERBY: And does the Fed have a good balance on that front right now, or could it –
MR. HARKER: I think so.
MR. DERBY: I mean, there’s obviously an opening in Atlanta coming, although he – I mean, Dennis was a markets guy.
MR. HARKER: Yeah. So I don’t know. I mean, that’s up to the board in Atlanta, obviously, to decide the choice they’re going to make, in conjunction with the governors. But I think right now we have a good balance. I mean, the conversation around the table is diverse in terms of people’s perspectives, and that’s healthy.
MR. DERBY: Is your – is the pragmatism that you bring to this, is it leading you to have any firming thoughts about how you think the economy works and how monetary policy should be conducted?
MR. HARKER: Right, so our best theory of the economy, right, is embodied in something like a DSGE model, right? And in that model, the two key words in there, it’s “dynamic” and “stochastic,” right? So there’s a lot of uncertainty in those models.
So what you know, having been an engineer and done control theory and optimization theory, right, you know the limits of those models as well, right? In any kind of dynamic control environment, which is embedded in that model and the way we think the economy works over time, a key component of any kind of complex system like that is that you need to learn by doing. That is, you can’t step back and say the model is a perfect or near-perfect representative of the system you’re trying to control or manage. You have to tweak it, move, learn; tweak it, move, learn, right? And so that’s what we know not even in economics, but in large dynamic stochastic systems.
I don’t think that’s any different with respect to macroeconomic policy. I think, as we move toward normalization, and if we believe the risks are balanced, which I do, then – and there are some risks that I’m worried about, such as some distortive effects of a low interest rate environment – then it’s time to move, and then see what happens, and then move. And so that’s what I mean by pragmatism. It’s understanding that theory, which I understand well. And as that applies to macroeconomics, it brings a more experimental flavor, I think, to the way you think, as opposed to an ideological point of view.
For me, I think that’s healthy because I know those kind of systems are inherently complex. The nonlinearity alone is complex, and then you add the stochastic nature, and there you should have a lot of humility to say we really don’t know exactly what’ll happen. That’s why we move cautiously, but move, to see what happens.
MR. DERBY: Well, in that way of thinking about things, I mean, there’s always been that axiom, you know, monetary policy works with long and variable lags.
And if you’re confronted with lots of uncertainty and you’re, you know, move, see what happens, but those see what happens are dynamics that play out over a long period of time –
MR. HARKER: They are, but then you see some of that future in things like expectations, whether they’re inflation expectations, market expectations. So you’re right, you’ll never perfectly know what’s going to happen, say, 18 months from now after you make that move, but you can get some glimpse of it with how markets respond and expectations become anchored or unanchored relative to such a move.
MR. DERBY: It seems as if there’s been – we see in the markets a lot of grumbling about the Fed communications or the guidance that the Fed has given, in that the Fed has not done with rates what the dot plot suggested it was going to do in December. Some market participants are, like, we were right, you know, we won, the Fed was wrong.
MR. HARKER: (Laughs.)
MR. DERBY: What do you think the dynamic is between financial markets and the Fed right now? Is it – is it a healthy dynamic? Or is there – is there a problem?
MR. HARKER: I don’t think there’s a problem. I do think the market is possibly underestimating the rate of normalization, but we’ll see, right?
And part of the challenge is, when it comes to communication, the dot plots are all forecasts, but people take the path of the Fed funds rate as a policy statement, not as a forecast. And we have not made that clear, right? We’re asked to forecast what we think the Fed funds rate will be. That’s a different question than saying, you know, what will the Fed funds rate be? And so that one dot plot I think causes us some problems when it comes to communication.
MR. DERBY: The December?
MR. HARKER: No, I’m just saying the path of the Fed funds rate. I think that causes us some communications challenges, because nobody says our dots for inflation or (gross domestic product) are anything other than a forecast. They take this one – and really, you think about what we’re asked: Given the path of the economy as we best know it, forecast it today, what do we think the Fed funds rate will be? But that’s not a promise that it will be that, right? And I think that’s been a challenge for us, because as things happen – as shocks, large or small, hit the economy – we have to react accordingly. We can’t stay on that predetermined path because it’s not a predetermined path.
MR. DERBY: So how do you fix it? I know (Cleveland Fed President) Loretta Mester’s talked about confidence bands. I know it’s a matter that the Communications Committee is considering. I don’t know if you’re on it. What would you like to see done differently?
MR. HARKER: So there are a lot of options. One is to add even more information with confidence bands. That’s one alternative.
The other – but it would be very difficult to do, that other central banks have done – is just get a consensus view. But we’re a large, diverse Committee. So that may work, but you know, we’d have to think about that carefully.
I mean, there are various options on how to do that.
MR. DERBY: So, but yeah, I mean, there’s nothing you particularly favor –
MR. HARKER: No, not at this point. I think we really – I need to weigh the pros and cons of that. We’re not far enough along, at least in my mind, to be able to make that decision.
MR. DERBY: And just the overall state of communications. I know there’s also been, you know, I mean, days when you’ll have four and five Fed officials speaking. The Dallas Fed had a paper that talked about maybe collectively people need to speak a little bit less and pick their – pick their spots a bit more.
MR. HARKER: Well, what do you think about that? (Laughs.)
MR. DERBY: Ah, you know, I mean, we take it as it comes. So, I mean, that’s not our place to rule in on that.
MR. HARKER: I don’t know, right? I mean, you have to be careful because the way the way the system is set up is to have – especially with the regional banks – is to have a diverse, independent view. And I think it’s – is it incumbent upon us to distill that view and to – or limit that view, or is it incumbent upon the public to distill that view, right? I mean, that’s the question, right? Should we limit what we communicate in terms of our diversity of views, or should we let the public and the media work with those diverse views? I’m more in the camp of the latter, because I think the more information we put out there it’s – the better, even if it’s not all – we’re not all saying the same thing in the same way.
MR. DERBY: OK. Well, back to the pragmatism question again. I mean, do you feel that that leaves you – and I’ll just ask this because this is often how central bankers get, you know, graded – but it does lead you to be so far more hawkish or dovish? I suppose in that you favored a rate rise in September that didn’t happen, that –
MR. HARKER: Yeah, I would tend to be because, again, I – as we discussed earlier, with the lags that we know are in such a dynamic stochastic system, I think it’s important that we take some move now and have a gradual path of normalization, as opposed to wait, wait, wait, and then have to have a steeper rise. I just think that’s prudent. And being a Philly guy, I’m more an Eagle.
MR. DERBY: Oh, yeah. (Laughter.) OK. I got to remember that one.
But on the other side of it, I mean, the Fed has undershot its inflation target for years. And the New York Fed just had a report yesterday that showed some – another little trailing off in inflation expectations. And I know they’ve – that report has shown at various points softening. And I know energy’s a big part of all of this, but you talk about the dual mandate, and one side of that mandate is still – still seems rather elusive.
MR. HARKER: But I’m seeing signs with some increase in health care inflation and others that that 2 percent target is – remember, there’s a long lag to that too, right? So I think we’re within the zone, with 1.7 percent core (personal consumption expenditures), where it is prudent to make a move sooner rather than later.
MR. DERBY: So you’re not a whites of their eyes type of –
MR. HARKER: No, because I think the lags are pretty long. And we know that, historically. So we could get behind the curve. And again, we’re talking about a 25-basis-point increase, which would leave policy still quite accommodative.
MR. DERBY: One of the things the Fed forecast changed was lowering the long-run – long-run growth rate. And I wanted to know where you – what you thought about it, because that was a – struck us as a fairly meaningful shift.
MR. HARKER: Yeah, and I lowered mine too primarily because of the neutral funds rate, right, R-star. Until we see that start to move up, and with that productivity, it’s hard to forecast that we’re going to see a robust growth. So we’ll – again, that is – we have to take that as it comes, because we don’t move R-star. Other policies do that. So we just have to accept that fact and do the best we can, given that we – in my view, as I said in the speech earlier, we don’t have a set of policies that are necessarily conductive to economic growth at this point. There are some challenges there.
MR. DERBY: Does the change in that view tell us anything about the Fed’s assessment of secular – I’m sorry – the secular stagnation argument?
MR. HARKER: The secular stagnation assumes there’s nothing that can be done to move R-star, right, by definition. I don’t believe that. I just don’t think monetary policy can move it. But I think there are things we can do to increase the potential of the economy.
MR. DERBY: So I’ve noticed that – I mean, you – that has been an emergent theme in a number of comments from Fed officials recently, about the limits of monetary policy and what could be done on the fiscal front or the other side of the equation. And why are we hearing more about that? Because you’ve spoken about it several times as well. So why –
MR. HARKER: Well, it is true, right? (Laughs.) And so I think, first, it’s true. And also it’s important that we communicate what we can’t do, right, because often people look at the Fed for solving problems that are really outside of not just our mandate, but, with the tools we have of monetary policy, our ability to effect that change.
MR. DERBY: Can you point to some examples of that?
MR. HARKER: Well, go back to the speech I made earlier, right? If we want long-term growth, it comes from population increase and productivity increase in the long run, right? If we don’t have population increase – and we know that’s been a pretty large part of what we’ve seen – we should expect slower growth. Just look at Japan as an example. There is nothing, in my view, monetary policy can really do if your economy is shrinking because the number of people you have is shrinking. You may be able to affect per capita GDP, but you can’t affect headline GDP if you – if you have a smaller population, unless you have some extraordinary productivity growth that, at least in the foreseeable future, in the planning horizon, is hard to see.
MR. DERBY: Do you think people are asking the Fed to do some of these things in part because the political process is so gummed up or paralyzed?
MR. HARKER: Yes.
MR. DERBY: So that’s part of it? And also, the extraordinary actions taken during the financial crisis, I’ve gotten the sense from some quarters, have given people the belief the Fed can do more, or is the magic thing that can fix everything, and so why not ask them to target this and target that now.
MR. HARKER: Right, right. And that is not – we can’t do that in theory nor in practice.
MR. DERBY: Well, what would you say to, say – I’m sure you’ve met with the Fed Up people, and then they’re pressing you not to raise rates because they want the –
MR. HARKER: Right.
MR. DERBY: – in their view, the recovery to spread out to everybody, and they think if you raise rates that’s not going to – that’s not going to happen.
MR. HARKER: No, I understand their frustration. I think the frustration is very real. I’ve been out and about in the community, not just meeting with Fed Up but meeting lots of people throughout the district. But the long-term solution there is back to this Agenda for Poverty and Prosperity that we have. It’s that three-legged stool. It’s jobs, skills that can – individuals can have, and the housing and the environment that they can live in to be productive. That’s going to – that’s going to move the needle. I think if – whether we change the Fed funds rate or not will have a – not anywhere near the effect that that set of changes in policy around workforce development, job creation and housing would have. And that’s why we’re really focused on that here.
MR. DERBY: Does that mean you have to interact with the political system more than otherwise would have been the case, say, in the past?
MR. HARKER: Well, I don’t know. I wasn’t here in the past, OK? (Laughs.)
MR. DERBY: Oh, well, but I mean just as – I mean, as a student of the institution.
MR. HARKER: Yeah. I think what – I think what we need to do is provide the intellectual research capability that the Fed has a lot of and train it – you know, put our lenses firmly on these issues, for two reasons. One is I think it’s the right thing to do. We’re not going to write the policy. We’re not going to decide the policy. But we can do the research that lays out the parameters of what most likely will and won’t work, right, and the costs and benefits of those.
But also, we’re not going to have the long-term growth if we don’t reach full potential. And a big part of reaching full potential in the economy is we can’t leave a lot of people behind, all right? It’s just – it’s not just going to hurt those individuals; it’s going to hurt the economy overall. That’s why I think it’s so important. If our job is maximum employment, we got to bring those people into the workforce. And I think just moving the Fed funds rate or holding it steady is not going to be very effective in doing that. It’s going to be these other issues.
MR. DERBY: Have you spoken with elected leaders –
MR. HARKER: Oh yeah.
MR. DERBY: – and got any sense that this is getting through?
MR. HARKER: Oh, they get it. Yeah, yeah.
MR. DERBY: OK.
MR. HARKER: But, you know, it’s a complicated time in our country. And again, this is not what – this is particularly one of these issues that’s not just a national issue. We tend to think of it as a national issue, but it’s community by community, city by city. You know, dealing with state leaders, city leaders, it’s really important.
You go across the river to Camden, and I spent some time over there and my mother was born in Camden. There’s a place that has a plan that they’ve put together with the administration in a bipartisan way – with the Christie administration to really bring Camden back, and do it in an inclusive way so you’re not just saying, oh, well, they’re gentrifying, but where do the gentrified go? We’re not solving the problem if the gentrified just get pushed to the edges. And so they’ve got a plan, and they’re executing that plan. And we’re doing some research there to sort of see how it plays out over time, what we can learn. That’s the kind of thing the Fed can do. We can step in and say, let’s bring our analytical capability to these issues and see what we can learn from these changes.
MR. DERBY: Well, at the national level, I got the sense from your remarks earlier today that political paralysis, or just an unwillingness of the two sides to engage, or the unwillingness of one side to engage with the other side, is a major problem for the economy right now. Did I hear that accurately?
MR. HARKER: Yeah. I mean, if – I think – you know, I think – I’ll put my citizen hat on, right, and not my Fed hat. (Laughs.)
MR. DERBY: OK.
MR. HARKER: Of course. That’s frustrating to everyone. And again, we see this in this partisan conflict index. We measure this. We know that this is elevated and it’s stayed elevated. And we know the implications of that, the results of that on economic growth: it’s not good. And so it – that’s where I think we are the Fed, with our research capability, can at least be a voice of nonpartisan, here are the facts as we know them, and you have to make use of these facts or not. It’s up to you. But this is what we know will or won’t work.
MR. DERBY: Well, in desiring to be nonpartisan, I mean, the Fed has been drug into the – or has been pulled into this election campaign in a way that I haven’t really seen before. I mean, does that – does that alarm you?
MR. HARKER: Yes. I can honestly say, in my (Federal Open Market Committee) meetings to date and my daily interactions around here, politics never enters the equation. I’ve just not seen that, right? Now, I don’t know what’s inside people’s heads, but I’ve never, ever seen it articulated in any way. People are just trying to do what they believe is the right thing with the right policy. So I think it’s unfair that we’ve been brought into this political situation because I think the strength of the Fed is that we stay independent and we stay nonpartisan. And I think the leadership of the Fed, myself included, are deeply committed to making sure that happens.
MR. DERBY: Do you think the Fed is well-suited that if it were to come under – I mean, if it were to come under strong political pressure to follow a certain policy line, would it be able to withstand that pressure?
MR. HARKER: I can’t speak for everybody else, but I could.
MR. DERBY: OK. I just figured I’d ask.
I wanted to ask you about the inflation target. There’s been some talk about raising it recently as one possible way to help address the R-star argument, among other things. So I’m curious where you stood on that matter.
MR. HARKER: Well, first, it would be good to get to 2 percent and then have that. (Laughs.) But I’m not sure increasing the inflation target will move R-star as much as just economic growth will move R-star. In which case, it would be nice if growth was that robust where we started to have the inflation target exceeded on a routine basis, and we’d have to rethink what that is. But we’re not there right now.
MR. DERBY: Right. But I thought part of the idea was that you communicate – in that you say this, that it exerts an influence.
MR. HARKER: Yeah, there are all – look, expectations are clearly a critical part of macroeconomics. That may have an effect. I’m more – and I won’t dismiss that effect. But I think the other policies will have a larger effect over time.
MR. DERBY: So you’re not looking for any changes in how the Fed approaches its inflation target right now? I know there’s another idea of, like, ending the bygones policy.
MR. HARKER: I don’t think right now. Until we get past where we are now towards something that one may consider more normal, I think it’s – then it’s time to revisit that.
MR. DERBY: OK. And I know we’ve talked a lot about – or just you’ve confronted these questions before – but just the Fed being ready or having tools in case it confronts another economic downturn.
MR. HARKER: Yeah. I mean, I – that’s another reason I am supportive of a slow but consistent path toward normalization, so we can get further and further away from zero. I think there are risks of hanging around zero too long. And if the economy can withstand it, I think it’s appropriate to move.
MR. DERBY: What would you say to people that say the entire reason why the stock market is at the levels that it’s at is because of near-zero rates and Fed actions, and –
MR. HARKER: Yeah, I’m always skeptical of somebody who says that the sole reason – the only reason is this. I think it is a contributing factor. Is it the only factor? No. But I do believe it’s a contributing factor. And I say that going back to my previous life as a corporate director. Again, you are looking at shareholder value, and you’re looking at shareholder value and how to enhance it. Well, in the long run, it is investing in new businesses, investing in new plant and equipment.
But you also can return value to the shareholder through dividends or stock buybacks. And if the debt is that cheap, it’s one of the things that your – one of the arrows in your quiver that you’re going to use. When debt is that cheap, you’re going to make that switch from equity to debt. And I think there is some truth in the fact that the equities markets reflect those individual decisions by companies that are perfectly rational for those companies to do in this low-rate environment.
MR. DERBY: Do you worry, though, that raising rates, as it starts to affect that calculus, starts to deflate or cause the stock market to sell off, and then that’s a negative input for confidence and it just causes things to come from that?
MR. HARKER: Not if we do it – not if we do it cautiously and pace the rate of normalization. If we have to do it quickly, I’d worry about that. But that’s why I don’t want to have a wait and then rapid rise later policy.
MR. DERBY: And do you believe – I mean, it sounds like from the meeting minutes people are coming around to there’s going to be an action relatively soon.
MR. HARKER: Yeah, again, I can’t speak for the Committee. But for me, I would like to see that sooner rather than later.
MR. DERBY: Take another step back and talk about some of the reform proposals that have been directed towards the Fed.
MR. HARKER: Sure.
MR. DERBY: One of the ideas – we’ll just go down them by the list – this will actually be (Dartmouth College economics professor) Andy Levin’s list in a way, but just because it kind of pulled together a lot of different things. But the quasi-private status of the regional Federal Reserve banks, I mean, that has been long something that has – outside critics have criticized the Fed for. You know, you hear arguments the Fed is just doing the work of the bankers that own it. If the Fed were to be made – regional Fed banks were to be made fully part of government, would it help address that criticism?
MR. HARKER: I don’t think so, because I – we’ll start with the fact that I don’t think the bankers – I can only speak for myself – influence my policy decisions, other than the information they give me on what’s happening in their communities.
And so one of the reform proposals is to remove bankers from the board, right? That would be part of this proposal. And I think that’s a mistake, because if I think about my board, we meet every 14 days, they vote on the discount rate, and I get information from them about what is going on in their communities. And that information, to me, is very important because data, by definition, is backward looking, right? You can only have data about what happened. They give me information about, for example, one banker was involved with a health care institution in his community. Nurses were getting a 9 percent raise and they were getting – teeing up for a possible other increase in their wages because they couldn’t find nurses. That’s actually helpful information. As we start to tease out the picture of where we’re seeing wage pressure, OK, that’s only one anecdote and you have to be careful of solo – you know, caution about anecdotes, but it still – it gives you some sense of the right questions to ask, right?
Similarly, asking the bankers and others on the board what they see with respect to business investment. We have a lot of data on that, but what are they seeing on the ground? What are people doing and not doing? And again, in our case, all the bankers are community bankers. They’re not (Large Institution Supervision Coordinating Committee) institutions. They’re institutions that are serving their local communities, and they’re part of the fabric of those local communities. Those voices are really important to me, and I’d hate to lose those.
MR. DERBY: You can’t have them on an advisory council and meet with them –
MR. HARKER: You could, but not every 14 days.
MR. DERBY: OK.
MR. HARKER: You’re not going to have any advisory council – (laughs) – I mean, we have a great advisory council, our Economic Community Advisory Council, chaired by Madeline Bell, who’s the head of Children’s Hospital here, one of the leading if not the leading children’s hospital in the world. But again, we meet on a regular basis, but not that frequently. And so I worry about losing information in that process.
MR. DERBY: OK. But on the matter of Fed ownership, I mean, you don’t see that – any conflicts coming from that structure?
MR. HARKER: It’s never affected – again, I can only – it’s never affected anything with respect to our policy stance – my policy stance.
MR. DERBY: And how do you ensure that, say, board members don’t get information about the policy outlook that other people – like, if it’s not being distributed, you know, broadly?
MR. HARKER: Yeah, I mean, they get the same economic update that we would give to any group as we run around the district and talk about – you know, our economists talking about issues. They don’t get any proprietary information. Everything we present to them, at least here in Philly, is publicly disclosed information.
MR. DERBY: There was a change that the New York Fed had made on its – how it handled the –
(Break.)
MR. DERBY: There we go. The New York Fed had made a change in how it briefed, or made – the president no longer gives a recommendation on what the discount rate should be, so that whatever the board votes from is entirely self – it comes from them now. And that way they don’t have any – they can’t draw an inference from what the president – say, President Dudley – tells them. Do you have that same policy here?
MR. HARKER: No. And I don’t get the sense, though – my board is quite independent. And as a director, I was quite independent. So I’m not sure that it has that kind of influence, at least in Philadelphia. I can’t speak for any other bank.
MR. DERBY: So you – just to be clear, I mean, you do it the traditional – you make a recommendation to them based on –
MR. HARKER: And the board is quite independent in their perspective on that.
MR. DERBY: OK. Actually, that is a question. I mean, from your – what’s different from – what’s changed in your perspectives from being on the board to being a president? What do you know now about how this all works that you didn’t know then?
MR. HARKER: I know a lot. (Laughter.)
So I think the biggest issue is outside of monetary policy. It’s just the complexity of the Federal Reserve system and everything that we do, right? When you sit in a board room, you have some sense of that, but you don’t get a deep dive in everything we’re doing in the community. And by definition, the board members have no access into supervisory information, right? Because we do – there is a real strict wall of separation there, other than anything that’s public information. So obviously, on this side, as the supervisors, as the regulators, I have a lot more information now than I ever had as a board member.
MR. DERBY: So it’s mostly an informational difference?
MR. HARKER: Yeah.
MR. DERBY: I think what people might find interesting: How much of your time do you spend on actual economic and monetary policy thinking and working, compared to the other demands of the job?
MR. HARKER: So, of course, it goes in cycles, right. There’s, I think, for me, eight times a year (inaudible) the FOMC. Then we have a conversation with the team here after the FOMC, just a sort of after-action report of, you know, what’s happening. I would say in any given cycle of eight times a year. So think of that roughly as six weeks; so a little more than a third. We may even be bumping up to half of that is spent on monetary-policy issues. Another big chunk of that is spent on regional development issues and community development issues, which I think feed into that view. And then there’s the day-to-day running a bank.
MR. DERBY: Yeah. I mean, it’s a large organization with a lot of stuff to do in services and –
MR. HARKER: Right. Right, right.
MR. DERBY: Yeah, interesting.
Back on the reform front, one thing we didn’t talk about was diversity. And that is now coming even more into the fore with what’s happening down in Atlanta with the congressman writing about, you know, their hopes for the pick down there. Can the Fed – can and should the Fed do better in terms of diversity, especially at its top leadership levels, again, when it comes to governors and bank presidents?
MR. HARKER: Yes.
MR. DERBY: OK.
MR. HARKER: So I think about Philadelphia. We’ve had a 20 percent increase in the diversity of our top leadership team here, and we’ve – and if I think about the board, we’ve tried to increase diversity there both in terms of ethnicity and gender. Our Economic Community Advisory Council, which gives us an insight into what’s happening in communities, but also an opportunity to engage people possibly being board members, that is quite diverse. Sixty percent of those members are either women, minorities, or both, because there’s overlap.
So I think we’re making progress, and I think with the staff as a whole. But there is an issue at the top, and as you mentioned, at the senior leadership within at least – I can only speak for this bank. And there’s a matter of working hard to bring people – bring them into the Fed system, get them the experiences they need to grow in leadership in the Fed, and to be prepared for those next steps. I think that’s an area I’m very committed to, because it starts with recruiting a diverse workforce here, or, in the case of directors, diverse directors, and having sort of feeder systems for that, whether it’s inside the bank and the system or outside that you could then draw from.
MR. DERBY: Well, I’ve heard the case made one of the problems is because the academic profession is tilted in the way that it is that academic economists have been historically tilted towards white men, and that’s just – that is the reality of who is in the profession. And so, therefore, as you’re looking for people to move up through it, it’s – that creates a –
MR. HARKER: I mean, as a former university president, it’s not just economics; (science, technology, engineering and mathematics) disciplines generally. That’s a problem. I think, in terms of gender, that’s starting to change in those disciplines. But it’s still a challenge for underrepresented groups. So I think that is a challenge.
But we need to then therefore look for leadership not necessarily out of that channel, right, and look for others, whether it’s coming from experience in the financial-services industry or other parts of academia or other industries altogether. I think we need to start broadening our thinking about that if we’re going to really change the nature of the leadership of the Federal Reserve. And I do think it’s important to do. I mean, we’re very committed – I’m very committed to that here. We’re making some progress, but we need to keep pushing.
MR. DERBY: Has the lack of diversity had any policy implications so far?
MR. HARKER: Well, in addition to diversity of ethnicity, gender, et cetera, it’s also important to have diversity of thought. And so I am concerned about avoiding group-think. So that, I think, has more policy implications than other forms of diversity, although I do think we need to have appropriate and important understanding of low-, moderate-income communities and what they’re facing. I think that is important. And that’s why we have really enhanced our efforts here in our community development, in this agenda, to really get a deeper, deeper understanding of what’s going on there, because that has to inform our policy as well. And so the leadership has to be informed by that. They don’t necessarily have to come from that. But they could, right? They potentially could.
MR. DERBY: Do you think the Philadelphia Fed is fixed to be a leader on, say, understanding the plight of low and –
MR. HARKER: I hope so. Yeah, I hope so, for two reasons. One, I think we have the talent here to do that. And second, it’s important to this district. If we’re going to serve the district, which is part of our charge, we have challenges in this district. We have a lot of opportunity, too, in Philadelphia, but we’ve got some challenges.
MR. DERBY: OK. Well, I often do this towards the end of interviews sometimes, but to ask if, I mean, if there is any issue or thing that you would like to see people talk about or point that you feel that you’ve been trying to make that might not be getting through. Kind of an open-ended question there, but I mean, is there something you think people need to understand about the Fed that they’re – it’s just not getting through? Is there anything like that?
MR. HARKER: I’d go back to our earlier conversation. I do think that people don’t quite understand the limits of what monetary policy can do, and therefore what the Fed can do. And we’re – we create the environment, the platform for the economy to grow, but we’re not going to drive that growth. As I said earlier in the Q&A after the speech, I think people – we don’t have the secret sauce all by ourselves that’s going to make the economy grow. It’s just not the way it works. And I think people don’t necessarily understand that. And I’m worried about that because I think we’re being asked to do more than we’re capable of.
Source
Group in Allentown rallies for immigration reform
The Morning Call - April 6, 2013 - ...
The Morning Call - April 6, 2013 - Whitehall Township resident Belkys Luvon doesn't expect all of America's undocumented immigrants to be granted U.S. citizenship overnight. That's not what she and other advocates of comprehensive reform of the country's immigration laws are lobbying for — or even what they'd want.
But Luvon, who said she came to the United States legally from the Dominican Republic 29 years ago, feels it only fair that undocumented immigrants be offered legal means of gaining citizenship.
Basically, what proponents call "a path to citizenship" should be for those who have lived here, abided by the law, worked hard, raised families and otherwise contributed to the well-being of countless communities, Luvon said.
She and other Lehigh Valley residents, as well as organizers from other areas, staged a public rally for immigration reform Saturday at Allentown's Cedar Creek Park. Only a few dozen people were on hand in the early going — the event got off to a late start — but support for the cause regionally, as well as nationally, is strong, according to Tony Perlstein of the Center for Popular Democracy inWashington, D.C., which supports reform.
In addition to the event in Allentown, "speak outs" for reform were scheduled in Norristown and other parts of Pennsylvania, and across the country, Perlstein said.
Luzon — who operates a consulting business helping immigrants attain citizenship, as well as with preparing income tax returns and starting businesses of their own — said she wants more people, regardless of status, to have the kind of opportunity granted to her.
"I consider myself lucky, thank God," she said, having followed her mother to America. "I believe it is fair, after living here and working hard" — and staying out of trouble with the law, she stressed — for people to have a path to citizenship as envisioned by PresidentBarack Obama, Luzon said.
Luzon objects to the term "illegal immigrants."
"No human being is illegal," she said.
Reform supporter Erika Sutherland, a Muhlenberg Collegeprofessor, said she hopes for a comprehensive package of reforms that streamlines existing programs for attaining citizenship and gives people a way to get on the path toward citizenship.
Among the goals, she said, is "an equitable comprehensive citizenship" for the estimated 11 million undocumented immigrants, the vast majority of whom are "people contributing to our community and [who] want nothing more than the ability to stay and work."
"We are a nation of immigrants," Sutherland concluded. "We can do better."
With a group of Republican and Democratic senators working on comprehensive reform, the Center for Popular Democracy expects tens of thousands of supporters at a demonstration Wednesday in Washington in favor of reform, Perlstein said.
Source
Why the Fed should target underemployment, not unemployment, as it sets interest rates
Why the Fed should target underemployment, not unemployment, as it sets interest rates
Members of the Fed Up Coalition protest during the Jackson Hole economic symposium in 2015....
Members of the Fed Up Coalition protest during the Jackson Hole economic symposium in 2015.
See the photo here.
Don't Tinker with Md.'s Charter School Law
The Baltimore Sun - January 12, 2015, by Betty Weller and Verjeana Jacobs - The headlines in other states warning...
The Baltimore Sun - January 12, 2015, by Betty Weller and Verjeana Jacobs - The headlines in other states warning against weak charter school laws are mounting. In May, a report from the Center for Popular Democracy and Integrity in Education found that unscrupulous charter school operators in 15 states had lost, misused or wasted more than $100 million in taxpayer money.
A yearlong investigation by the Detroit Free Press found that Michigan's weak charter school law resulted in the state spending $1 billion annually on schools with little transparency, consistently poor results and questionable financial practices.
And in September, community groups in Philadelphia released a report finding that charter school officials had defrauded students and schools of at least $30 million since 1997.
Most recently, Ohio's Republican governor, John Kasich, spoke about the dire need to strengthen state regulation of charter schools to stem poor performance and financial mismanagement.
Fortunately, Maryland has not experienced these problems, thanks to the state's strong charter school law. Since 2003, Maryland's Charter School Act has promoted high standards, real accountability to students, parents and communities, and sound financial management.
That this track record of success has been questioned recently by The Sun is deeply troubling ("More choices for parents and students," Dec. 21).
It makes little sense to label a law "weak" because it holds charter schools to the same high academic and financial management standards as other public schools.
Maryland's charter school law has protected us from the "worst-case scenarios" of financial mismanagement, persistently failing schools and conflicts between local communities and charter school operators that have plagued states with weaker laws than ours.
Ensuring local school board oversight and highly qualified teachers in the classroom are hallmarks of Maryland's charter school law. We need to protect Maryland's strong charter school law to ensure that charter schools are run well, and that all students, whether they're in a charter or a traditional public school, receive high quality instruction.
Source
The Fed Just Inched Closer To Raising Interest Rates
The Federal Reserve announced on Wednesday that it will keep interest rates at or near zero for now, but implied it...
The Federal Reserve announced on Wednesday that it will keep interest rates at or near zero for now, but implied it would soon raise them, alarming left-leaning activists and economists concerned about stagnant wages.
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), which is the central bank’s body responsible for managing key interest rates, said in a statement that its decision was based on the conclusion that interest rates of zero to 0.25 percent -- known as the “zero lower bound” -- were still needed to “support continued progress toward maximum employment and price stability.” The statement refers to the Fed’s dual mandate to both pursue full employment and keep inflation low through its control of the money supply.
The FOMC said that inflation in particular continues to remain too low to warrant an interest rate hike.
“Inflation continued to run below the Committee's longer-run objective, partly reflecting earlier declines in energy prices and decreasing prices of non-energy imports,” the committee said in the statement.
However, the Fed also indicated in its statement that it is optimistic about the pace of economic growth, buoying expectations of a rate hike in September when the FOMC meets next. Many analysts have been predicting that the Fed would raise rates as soon as September, or at least before the year’s end.
The FOMC statement noted that “economic activity has been expanding moderately in recent months. The labor market continued to improve, with solid job gains and declining unemployment.”
The Fed has kept the primary interest rate it controls near zero since December 2008.
Many activists and economists, including the left-leaning nonprofit Center for Popular Democracy’s Fed Up campaign, believe that the Fed has prioritized the inflation half of its dual mandate at the expense of full employment. They argue against raising rates before unemployment gets low enough for employers to raise wages. And they are especially considered that unemployment rates remain disproportionately high in communities of color.
The Fed Up campaign was pleased that the Fed did not raise rates on Wednesday, but called the lack of a rate hike a “low bar,” since it was not even expected by most observers. Instead, the campaign emphasized its frustration with the FOMC statement for ignoring signs of slack in the job market.
“The FOMC statement hails ‘solid job gains,’ but does not mention that the most recent job figures showed a slowdown in wages,” said Jordan Haedtler, deputy campaign manager for Fed Up. “The downward trend in wages is a major reason why the Fed should not raise interest rates in 2015.”
Source: Huffington Post
18 hours ago
20 hours ago