Parsippany contractor fined $3.2M for underpaying immigrant labor
Parsippany contractor fined $3.2M for underpaying immigrant labor
New York City Comptroller Scott M. Stringer on Tuesday assessed $3.2 million in fines against a Parsippany-based...
New York City Comptroller Scott M. Stringer on Tuesday assessed $3.2 million in fines against a Parsippany-based contractor for cheating dozens of workers out of the prevailing wages and benefits they were owed under the New York State Labor Law.
K.S. Contracting Corp. and its owner, Paresh Shah, also will be barred from working on New York City and State contracts for five years.
“With President Trump taking clear aim at immigrants across the country, we need to stand up and protect the foreign-born New Yorkers who keep our city running. Every New Yorker has rights, and my office won’t back down in defending them,” Stringer said. “Contractors might think they can take advantage of immigrants, but today we’re sending a strong message: my office will fight for every worker in New York City. This is about basic fairness and accountability.”
K.S. Contracting was named as one of the worst wage theft violators in New York in a report by the Center for Popular Democracy in 2015. The majority of the workers impacted were immigrants of Latino, South Asian, or West Indian descent.
An Internet search produced two Parsippany addresses for K.S. Contracting, both listing Shah as the owner. The number listed for an office at 342 Parsippany Road has been disconnected. A woman answering a call to the other Parsippany location listed for the company, a residential address at 29 Phillip Drive, said no one by the name Paresh Shah was there, and "no contracting."
Paresh Shah is listed in New Jersey tax records as the owner at 29 Phillip Drive.
According to Stringer's statement announcing the penalties, K.S. Contracting was awarded more than $21 million in contracts by the City Departments of Design and Construction, Parks and Recreation, and Sanitation between 2007 and 2010. Those projects included the Morrisania Health Center in the Bronx, the 122 Community Center in Manhattan, the Barbara S. Kleinman Men’s Residence in Brooklyn, the North Infirmary Command Building on Rikers Island, Bronx River Park, the District 15 Sanitation Garage in Brooklyn, and various city sidewalks in Queens.
The comptroller’s office began investigating the company after an employee filed a complaint with the office in May 2010. The multi-year investigation used subpoenas, video evidence, union records, and city agency data to uncover a kickback scheme that preyed on immigrant workers.
Stringer's statement included a video shot with a hidden camera by a foreman on several of the aforementioned construction jobs. A comptroller's office spokesperson said the foreman, who was cooperating with authorities as a victim of the scheme, is seen handing $4,982 in cash to the K.B. manager in a car and asking the manager to count it. The manager then takes the cash out of an envelope and counts it.
According to the comptroller's office, the cash was the proceeds of paychecks distributed to workers, who then cashed the checks and gave it back to the foreman.
After a four-day administrative trial in May 2016, Stringer found that K.S. Contracting routinely issued paychecks to just half of its workforce and then required those employees to cash the checks and surrender the money to company supervisors. The Comptroller further found that those supervisors would then redistribute the cash to all of the employees on a jobsite, paying them at rates significantly below prevailing wages. Stringer added that the company falsely reported to city agencies that all employees on the job site who received checks were paid the prevailing wage.
Between August 2008 and November 2011, the company cheated at least 36 workers out of $1.7 million in wages and benefits on seven New York City public works projects, stringer said. K.S. Contracting reported that it paid its workers combined wage and benefit rates starting at $50 per hour but actually paid daily cash salaries starting at $90 per day.
The New York City Comptroller’s office enforces state and local laws which require private contractors working on New York City public works projects or those with service contracts with City agencies to pay no less than the prevailing wage or living wage rate to their employees.
When workers are underpaid, the New York City Comptroller’s office works to recoup the amount of the underpayment plus interest.
By William Westhoven
Source
How "Abolish ICE" Went From A Twitter Slogan To A Litmus Test
How "Abolish ICE" Went From A Twitter Slogan To A Litmus Test
That sentiment — that he has helped popularize a longtime activist goal — is echoed by other activists as well as...
That sentiment — that he has helped popularize a longtime activist goal — is echoed by other activists as well as McElwee himself. “There is a segment of the immigration rights community," said Ana Maria Archila, co–executive director of Center for Popular Democracy, "that has looked at the laws of immigration and the enforcement of those laws as a core component of the criminalization apparatus in this country that is designed to keep black and brown communities subjugated. Sean did a lot of work to explain the history of the agency and insert this into the mainstream political discourse.”
Read the full article here.
Should New Orleans Allow Undocumented Immigrants to Get City-issued ID Cards?
The Times-Picayune - December 16, 2014, by Robert McClendon - One of the centerpieces of New Orleans Councilwoman...
The Times-Picayune - December 16, 2014, by Robert McClendon - One of the centerpieces of New Orleans Councilwoman LaToya Cantrell's pro-immigrant policy package is a proposed municipal identification card program.
Let us know what you think of the idea by taking the poll below and sharing your views in the comment section.
ID cards are used in so many bureaucratic and commercial interactions that they are easy to take for granted. They are often required during interactions with police, when registering children for school and when opening open bank accounts.
Undocumented immigrants, however, are frequently unable to obtain what has become the most common form of government issued identification: the drivers license.
Louisiana, like many states, has strict eligibility rules for drivers licenses, requiring applicants to prove that they are either American citizens or in the country legally.
Without a state-issued ID, undocumented immigrants are frequently unable to accomplish basic tasks, according to advocacy groups. And, with Congress seemingly hopelessly deadlocked on a reform that would normalize the status of immigrants in the country illegally, that situation is unlikely to change any time soon.
Thus, groups like the center for popular democracy, a left-wing advocacy group, are pushing for cities to take matters into their own hands by creating municipal identification cards that do not require applicants to prove they are in the country legally.
The idea is still relatively new. The first community thought to have created a city-ID program is New Haven, Connecticut, which launched its program in 2007. It's unclear how many cities nationwide have followed suit.
A white paper issued by the Center for Popular Democracy says that other cities with local ID programs include: San Francisco; New York; Richmond, California; Oakland, California; Los Angeles; Washington DC and several municipalities in New Jersey.
Critics of such programs say they undermine security by making it easier to obtain government identification and some have said it will make it easier for non-citizens to vote.
Anti-immigrant hardliners have said they like the strict state laws in place precisely because they make life more difficult for immigrants. The harder life is for immigrants, the more likely they are to "self deport," the activists say.
A city-issued ID program is among many policy changes that Cantrell says she will propose in a non-binding resolution early next year.
Source
Charter School Cheats: New Report On Charter Industry Exposes $100 million In Taxpayer Funds Meant For Children Instead Lost To Fraud, Waste & Abuse
ProgressOhio - May 16, 2014 - A new report released today reveals that fraudulent charter operators in 15 states are...
ProgressOhio - May 16, 2014 - A new report released today reveals that fraudulent charter operators in 15 states are responsible for losing, misusing or wasting over $100 million in taxpayer money.
“Charter School Vulnerabilities to Waste, Fraud And Abuse,” authored by the Center for Popular Democracy and Integrity in Education, echoes a warning from the U.S. Department of Education’s Office of the Inspector General. The report draws upon news reports, criminal complaints and more to detail how, in just 15 of the 42 states that have charter schools, charter operators have used school funds illegally to buy personal luxuries for themselves, support their other businesses, and more.
The report also includes recommendations for policymakers on how they can address the problem of rampant fraud, waste and abuse in the charter school industry. Both organizations recommend pausing charter expansion until these problems are addressed.
“We expected to find a fair amount of fraud when we began this project, but we did not expect to find over $100 million in taxpayer dollars lost. That’s just in 15 states. And that figure fails to capture the real harm to children. Clearly, we should hit the pause button on charter expansion until there is a better oversight system in place to protect our children and our communities,” said Kyle Serrette, the Director of Education Justice at the Center for Popular Democracy.”
“Our school system exists to serve students and enrich communities,” added Sabrina Stevens, Executive Director of Integrity in Education. “School funding is too scarce as it is; we can hardly afford to waste the resources we do have on people who would prioritize exotic vacations over school supplies or food for children. We also can’t continue to rely on the media or isolated whistleblowers to identify these problems. We need to have rules in place that can systematically weed out incompetent or unscrupulous charter operators before they pose a risk to students and taxpayers.”
You can read the report by going to www.integrityineducation.org or www.populardemocracy.org.
Source
LA Joins NYC, Chicago in Push to Naturalize Permanent Residents
89.3 KPCC - September 17, 2014, by Josie Huang - Mayor Eric Garcetti has joined a new campaign that encourages the...
89.3 KPCC - September 17, 2014, by Josie Huang - Mayor Eric Garcetti has joined a new campaign that encourages the estimated 390,000 legal permanent residents in Los Angeles to become citizens for their own benefit — and the city's.
The “Cities for Citizenship" project, funded by $1.1 billion from corporate partner Citigroup, is also kicking off in New York and Chicago.
In Los Angeles, a quarter-million dollar allocation will go toward introducing financial literacy to citizenship classes at city libraries, said Linda Lopez, chief of the Mayor's Office of Immigrant Affairs. The cost of applying for citizenship — $680 — is prohibitive for many, and Lopez said new curriculum will teach students about saving for the naturalization process, as well as other aspects of their lives.
The new initiative will also help fund citizenship drives at community centers and outreach to employers in sectors with high concentrations of permanent residents, such as hospitality, health care and technology, Lopez said.
Lopez said the city is eager to boost civic engagement among its residents.
"Naturalization really offers the opportunity to participate in local and community affairs either through voting and different advocacy work," Lopez said. Cities also benefit financially when residents naturalize, said Andrew Friedman of the non-profit Center for Popular Democracy which has partnered with the cities.
He said studies have shown that citizens earn 8 to 11 percent more than permanent residents.
"Some of it has to do with more job opportunities, a higher degree of comfort on the part of employers," he said. "Folks are also able to access higher-paying industry jobs than they might as legal permanent residents though they have work authorization.
The center co-authored a report with the University of Southern California and The National Partnership for New Americans that found if half of those eligible sought citizenship, as much as $3 billion could flow to the L.A. economy over 10 years. Financial giant Citigroup said in a statement it wanted to help immigrant families see "direct economic benefits."
Citi's Global Director of Community Development Bob Annibale said: "Citi believes that citizenship is an asset that enables low-income immigrants to gain financial capability, and building a national identity must go hand-in-hand with building a financial identity."
Source
Press Release New Report Reveals Unscrupulous Employers Involved With Wage Theft in New York
Press Release New Report Reveals Unscrupulous Employers Involved With Wage Theft in New York
Today, Center for Popular Democracy Action releases the first major report on New York wage theft since 2009. The...
Today, Center for Popular Democracy Action releases the first major report on New York wage theft since 2009. The report, By a Thousand Cuts: The Complex Face of Wage Theft in New York, identifies 11 ‘bad actors’, which are employers with a history of wage theft that is either particularly egregious or that exemplifies a broader trend in key New York sectors.
The companies highlighted in the report have a history of committing various wage theft violations, such as denying benefits, failing to pay overtime or minimum wage, making illegal deductions from pay checks, telling workers to work off the clock, and misclassifying workers as freelancers or independent contractors to avoid paying benefits.
Despite passage of the Wage Theft Prevention Act of 2010, which gives New York the strongest laws in the nation, an estimated 2.1 million New Yorkers are still victims of wage theft annually, cheated out of a cumulative $3.2 billion in wages and benefits they are owed. The report contains never-before-released testimonies from impacted workers.
Protesters from The New York Coalition against Wage Theft gathered at 11 a.m. in front of a worksite run by asbestos removal company New York Insulation Inc., one of the bad actors identified in the report.
“New Yorkers are being cheated out of their hard earned wages, and it has to stop now,” said New York City Comptroller Scott M. Stringer. “The bottom line is that an honest day’s work deserves an honest day’s pay –and if a company cheats workers out of their wages, we will catch them and they will pay. I commend Make the Road New York and the Center for Popular Democracy for issuing this new report and continuing the fight against wage theft.”
“Despite good laws on the books, wage theft continues at epidemic proportions impacting millions of workers each year. It is, in effect, a massive crime wave that costs New Yorkers billions and exacerbates poverty and inequity in our state,” says Meg Fosque, low-wage organizing director at Make the Road.
“Wage theft is a pervasive crime, rather than the practice of a few unscrupulous employers. And, companies build business strategies on the bet that they will never be called to account for stealing their employees’ wages and undercutting high-road businesses. We need robust and resourced enforcement efforts to protect workers’livelihoods and the ability of fair employers to do business,” says Connie Razza, Director of Strategic Research at the Center for Popular Democracy.
"The depth and breadth of the wage theft problem is crippling our economy. The construction industry, tax payers, and workers all equally feel the pain of wage theft. This is not a victimless crime. When responsible contractors operating within the laws of New York State are put at a disadvantage against those ignoring these same laws, we must all unite to fix this problem," says Patrick J. Purcell, Executive Director with Greater New York LECET.
###
www.populardemocracy.org The Center for Popular Democracy promotes equity, opportunity, and a dynamic democracy in partnership with innovative base-building organizations, organizing networks and alliances, and progressive unions across the country. CPD builds the strength and capacity of democratic organizations to envision and advance a pro-worker, pro-immigrant, racial justice agenda.
Fed Pressed on Questions of Diversity
Fed Pressed on Questions of Diversity
The Federal Reserve faces criticism from lawmakers and others over its record on diversity at the same time the central...
The Federal Reserve faces criticism from lawmakers and others over its record on diversity at the same time the central bank is highlighting the economic outlook for minority groups.
Several Democrats on the Senate Banking Committee questioned Fed Chairwoman Janet Yellen on Tuesday about the selection process for regional Fed bank presidents, echoing the concerns of advocacy groups who have said the system should be more open and allow more public input.
The 12 regional bank presidents are appointed by regional boards, subject to approval by the Washington, D.C.-based Fed board of governors. As heads of regional Fed branches, they are expected to keep their fingers on the pulse of their local economies and participate on decisions about interest rates. Just two of the current presidents are women and none are black or Hispanic. The last black president stepped down in 1974.
Sen. Elizabeth Warren (D., Mass.) criticized the selection process, saying Washington officials represented little more than a rubber stamp. Earlier this year, Fed governors signed off on the reappointment of most bank presidents until 2021 “without any public debate or any public discussion,” she said.
“If you’re concerned about this, why didn’t you use either of these opportunities to say enough is enough. Let’s go back and see if we can find qualified regional presidents who also contribute to the overall diversity of the Fed’s leadership?” Ms. Warren asked.
“It just shows me that the selection process for regional Fed presidents is broken,” retorted Ms. Warren, calling on Congress to consider changing the process.
The Center for Popular Democracy, a left-leaning advocacy group, has been pressing the Fed for months to increase the diversity of its leadership, as have many Democrats on Capitol Hill who signed onto a letter from Ms. Warren to Ms. Yellen on the matter last month.
Presumptive Democratic presidential nominee Hillary Clinton has also weighed in. Her campaign released a statement saying the Fed “needs to be more representative of America as a whole.”
In a June 13 response to the lawmakers’ letter, Ms. Yellen acknowledged “there is still work to be done” on diversity within the Fed ranks “and I assure you that workforce diversity remains a priority for the Federal Reserve.”
In her prepared testimony Tuesday, Ms. Yellen stressed the need to ensure that the gains from the economic recovery are widely distributed.
She noted that blacks and Hispanics are still suffering some of the effects of the recession in more pronounced ways than other groups. Black and Hispanic workers still face higher unemployment rates than the workforce as a whole, she said.
“It is troubling that unemployment rates for these minority groups remain higher than for the nation overall, and that the annual income of the median African-American household is still well below the median income of other U.S. households,” Ms. Yellen said.
Diverging economic circumstances between white and black households predate the recession but the gaps widened after the financial crisis and have only barely narrowed in the recovery.
A Fed report released alongside Ms. Yellen’s testimony found that black households, which saw their median incomes fall 16% during the recession, are only 88% of the way back to prerecession levels. White households, by contrast, saw incomes fall only 8% and are already back to 94% of prerecession levels, the report said.
It is rare for the Fed to address the economic conditions for individual demographic groups. The central bank’s congressional mandate requires that it seek to hold down unemployment and keep inflation stable for the country as a whole. In the past, Ms. Yellen has said she was sympathetic to the economic troubles of minority groups but stressed the Fed’s options for addressing them were limited.
Ms. Yellen’s comments Tuesday suggest a rising recognition within the Fed that the racial gaps in the economy are becoming more pronounced and that there is a role for monetary policy to play in shrinking those gaps.
“It’s important for us to be aware of those differences and to focus on them as we think about monetary policy and work that the Federal Reserve does in the area of community development,” she said.
Ms. Yellen is set to address the House Financial Services Committee on Wednesday and could face many of the same questions.
By David Harrison
Source
New York City Council Passes Bill Forcing Employers to Provide Paid Sick Leave
The New American - May 9th, 2013 - On Wednesday the New York City Council...
The New American - May 9th, 2013 - On Wednesday the New York City Council voted 45-3 to pass the New York City Earned Sick Time Act, a bill that will require employers with more than 20 employees to provide five paid sick days to each of them every year while mandating that those employees using their sick days can’t be fired. The law would become effective on January 1, 2014, and companies with more than 15 employees would be required to comply with the law starting in 2015.
Even if Mayor Bloomberg vetoes the bill, the council will likely override it, making the law effective anyway. This will impact the employers of more than one million employees who currently have no paid sick days provided for them. The costs to be borne by those employers weren't provided in any public announcements.
The AFL/CIO explained why such legislation was needed:
In addition to the potential loss of wages for working families, the lack of paid sick days forces many people to go to work when they are contagious and [make] co-workers and customers sick.
No paid sick time also decreases [the] productivity for workers who show up unable to perform to their normal level of ability.
The Center for Popular Democracy (CPD) was joyous over the vote, calling it “a historic agreement to give over one million New Yorkers the right to take paid days off from work to care for themselves or a sick family member. The new legislation represents a major step forward for workers’ rights.” The CPD was joined by Make the Road New York; 32 BJ SEIU, the largest property service workers union; NYC City Council’s Progressive Caucus; the Working Families Party; A Better Balance; and the NY Paid Sick Leave Coalition.
Bill Lipton of the Working Families Party was equally ecstatic: "This is a sweet victory. It provides economic security for New Yorkers, and a shot in the arm for the paid sick days movement across the country."
The bill was first introduced by council member Gale Brewer, a permanent politician and long-time progressive political activist, back in July 2009 but went nowhere for nearly four years, owing to resistance by City Council Speaker Christine Quinn. Quinn’s change to allow a vote coincided nicely with her announcement in March to run to succeed Mayor Bloomberg.
Brewer exulted in the victory:
After 4 years of non-stop advocacy and coalition building, I want to thank the Paid Sick Days Coalition members and my Council colleagues with all my heart for support [of my bill] and never giving up.
I also extend my thanks to Speaker Quinn and her staff for their contributions to this legislation….
The argument over [paid sick leave] was always about common sense and fairness. I believe this law enshrines the principle that American exceptionalism is not just about large profits and small elites, but a workplace that is safe, fair and respectful of the lives of workers.
Approximately one million New Yorkers will now have the fundamental right to a paid day off when they or a family member falls ill, and no worker will be fired if they must stay home. This is a tremendous accomplishment of which all fair-minded New Yorkers can be proud.
Four major cities have already passed paid sick leave laws — Portland (Oregon), San Francisco, Seattle, and Washington, D.C. — while similar measures are being considered in 20 others. On the national level, two other progressives, Sen. Tom Harken (D-Iowa) and Rep. Rose DeLauro (D-Conn.), are pushing the Healthy Families Act, which proposes essentially the same thing as Brewer’s bill: seven paid sick days each year required to be paid for by employers with more than 15 employees. The National Partnership for Women & Families outlined the benefits of such national legislation:
• Paid sick days provide families with economic security;
• Providing paid sick days is cost effective to employers;
• Paid sick days reduce community contagion;
• Paid sick days can decrease health care costs.
Each of these assumptions can be rebutted successfully, but none does it better than Ayn Rand, who always asked “At whose expense?” and Henry Hazlitt in his book Economics in One Lesson, which also asked about the unseen consequences of such meddling. The "broken window fallacy" is also helpful in understanding what progressives refuse to see: Someone must pay for such mandates, usually someone silent or impotent, without enough political influence to stop such “progress” — usually the taxpayers or employers unlucky enough to have a successful business large enough to be included in the mandate.
Some of the unseen consequences would naturally include higher employment costs to the business owners, as these are, in effect, pay raises to employees. The business owners' higher costs would be reflected in higher prices to consumers, which would likely reduce competitive advantage in a market niche. More likely, however, owners will discover that they can’t afford all the people working for them and will be forced to reduce their payrolls through terminations or attrition. That will increase social costs, as those no longer working will start receiving unemployment benefits provided by the state.
In the longer run, however, making employers less competitive will shrink rather than expand the general economy. Some will not hire new workers. Others may decide to retire, deciding that it’s no longer worth the effort, as government becomes more and more intrusive. Still others may choose to move out of the city, or the state, to more tax-friendly environments, further reducing the city’s economic output.
The biggest cost of all, however, is the continued and growing acceptance of government intervention as a way to solve perceived social “problems” and giving progressives more opportunities to expand the power and reach of government
Perhaps the best rebuttal is to review the bill of rights of another country, well-known to historians, which also had a progressive agenda very similar to that of Quinn, Brewer, and the AFL/CIO. It stated:
Citizens … have the right to work, that is, are guaranteed the right to employment and payment for their work in accordance with its quantity and quality….
Citizens … have the right to rest and leisure … the reduction of the working day to seven hours … [and] the institution of annual vacations with full pay….
Citizens … have the right to maintenance in old age and also in case of sickness or loss of capacity to work … ensured by the extensive development of social insurance for workers and employees. [Emphasis added.]
These are, of course, the rights enshrined in the 1936 Constitution of the USSR.
A graduate of Cornell University and a former investment advisor, Bob is a regular contributor to The New American magazine and blogs frequently at www.LightFromTheRight.com, primarily on economics and politics. He can be reached at badelmann@thenewamerican.com.
Source
Transcript: WSJ Interview With Philadelphia Fed’s Patrick Harker
Transcript: WSJ Interview With Philadelphia Fed’s Patrick Harker
Patrick T. Harker, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, sat down for an interview with The Wall...
Patrick T. Harker, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, sat down for an interview with The Wall Street Journal’s Michael S. Derby on Thursday, Oct. 13, 2016. Here is a transcript of the exchange, lightly edited for length and clarity.
MICHAEL S. DERBY: So we already talked about a lot of the economic and monetary policy stuff. And we just met, so I’m not going to keep getting you to say the same things over and over again. And since I knew this – we were going to be talking after, you know, the speech – I thought we might sort of take a step back and think about, you know, you’ve been in the job a year and a – I mean, a little over a year now.
And, you know, you come to the position from a different background than some other central bankers do. I mean, there’s a lot of economists and research directors who’ve come up, or people from the financial sector. And so I figure I’d start off by asking you just your sense of, you know, like how it’s been, you know, coming in, and what kind of things you’ve learned about the job, and the challenges you’ve faced so far as you, you know, come to lead this institution.
You know, a little bit about my background. While I have degrees in engineering, I also have a degree in economics. I’m published a lot in spatial economics, so micro/spatial economics, what are called Takayama-Judge models or all-trade models. So – (laughs) – yeah. And then – and in addition to that, I’m a quant. So it’s not as though I came to the job with no understanding of the economics that underlie what we do. So let me start with that.
It’s been a really great first – little over first year for a couple of reasons. One, this role is not only important at the national level with respect to monetary policy, which is always the headline event for the Fed and the (Federal Open Market Committee), but I really enjoy the work we’re doing at the regional level, and really trying to create a better environment for job creation and economic mobility and inclusiveness for the economy here. You know, and Philadelphia, the Third District, is uniquely challenged given that we are the poorest top 10 city in America. We have communities throughout our district that are struggling. And so I think the Fed, through our research capability, our ability to convene people, we can have meaningful conversations about that and really start to create more and more opportunity. That’s why we launched this Agenda for Poverty and Prosperity, right?
So we’ve got a challenge here. I think that challenge is also national, but we have it uniquely here in Philadelphia, in the region. And even despite the fact that Philadelphia as a city itself is doing quite well, we need to start bringing more people into the economy productively, first and foremost for those people, but also for the economy. I mean, as I discussed in the speech just prior to this, we need more people in the workforce. And so immigration may be part of that solution, but a substantial component of that, just you look at the numbers, are bringing more people – unskilled people into job-training programs and workforce-development programs to get the jobs they need, and then have those jobs for them, and that they’re able to live somewhere near those jobs, right? It’s no good to have the jobs and have the skills and not be able to get to the job, right? So I think it’s a three-legged stool that we’re trying to develop here.
You know, and that’s – this is a – the other thing, to answer your specific question, is this is an incredible team of people. I mean, I’ve been really – I got to know them a little bit when I was director here, but you only get to meet certain people, right? Now I’ve been out and about in the Bank and in the community and see what we do, and, boy, it’s really impressive what the Philly Fed does. And I think you multiply that across the system.
MR. DERBY: What have you been doing to – I mean, if you come – like, as you say, you do have the M.A. in economics and you’ve done – you’ve done work in that area. But, like, as you’ve been – and you were director, obviously.
MR. HARKER: Yes.
MR. DERBY: So you weren’t unattached to what the institution was doing. But your predecessors – say Charles Plosser, I mean, he had some very strong views on monetary policy and the economy.
MR. HARKER: Yeah. Yeah, yeah.
MR. DERBY: And what have you been doing to come into your own on that front?
MR. HARKER: So I tend to be more of a pragmatist. And first you start with a little bit of humility on what we really know and the state of theory and practice when it comes to macroeconomics. Despite a lot of advances – and we’ve made a lot of advances in the field – there’s still a lot of things we don’t know, I mean, at a fairly fundamental level, right? I mean, we still debate questions on measuring inflation and inflation dynamics, measuring GDP and GDP – what’s happening with productivity. So you come into this understanding that while we have a deep bench of theorists and empiricists that need to inform policy, at the end of the day you need to base your judgment not on an ideology, but on the facts on the ground, right, as best we know them. And I think that’s what I bring to the table.
And then part of that is, you know, engineers are inherently pragmatic by nature. You know, the old engineering joke, the optimist says the glass is half-full, the pessimist says it’s half-empty, the engineer says you’ve got twice as much glass as you need there. (Laughter.)
MR. DERBY: I haven’t heard that joke, but yeah, that’s a good one.
MR. HARKER: So I think – and it’s part of, I think, the portfolio of talent that the Fed has attracted. You don’t want everybody to have the same background. You don’t want everybody to have the same life experiences. So you need some people in the room who have come from different experiences. You need some people in the room, I believe, who have actually worked on the other side of the financial markets – actually participating in the financial markets, not just regulating them, right, and theorizing about them. So I think you need – it’s the mix that makes for the richness of the conversation that happens in the room.
MR. DERBY: Has the Fed been too dominated by academics, and especially academic economists? Because that’s been one of the criticisms the Fed has faced at various points over the years.
MR. HARKER: So that’s an interesting question because I think that the Fed has – over time it cycles. You need some base knowledge of economic theory to be able to meaningfully participate in the conversation, but you can get that in different ways, right? You also, I think, need some understanding of markets and market functioning, right? And you can learn that, but it’s better if you’ve had some of that experience. And lastly, I think you need in the room – not everybody brings – you know, not everybody has all three of these things I’m saying at once, right, but it’s the mix of people. You need people with practical industry experience. And again, you can either get that by having run large institutions, for-profit, nonprofit; being on corporate boards, so they get some sense of how that decision process – that all has to be in the mix. But at the base we still need those economists, right, because ultimately we are dominated by, you could say – but really for a good reason – that base of economic talent because that’s the business we’re in.
MR. DERBY: And does the Fed have a good balance on that front right now, or could it –
MR. HARKER: I think so.
MR. DERBY: I mean, there’s obviously an opening in Atlanta coming, although he – I mean, Dennis was a markets guy.
MR. HARKER: Yeah. So I don’t know. I mean, that’s up to the board in Atlanta, obviously, to decide the choice they’re going to make, in conjunction with the governors. But I think right now we have a good balance. I mean, the conversation around the table is diverse in terms of people’s perspectives, and that’s healthy.
MR. DERBY: Is your – is the pragmatism that you bring to this, is it leading you to have any firming thoughts about how you think the economy works and how monetary policy should be conducted?
MR. HARKER: Right, so our best theory of the economy, right, is embodied in something like a DSGE model, right? And in that model, the two key words in there, it’s “dynamic” and “stochastic,” right? So there’s a lot of uncertainty in those models.
So what you know, having been an engineer and done control theory and optimization theory, right, you know the limits of those models as well, right? In any kind of dynamic control environment, which is embedded in that model and the way we think the economy works over time, a key component of any kind of complex system like that is that you need to learn by doing. That is, you can’t step back and say the model is a perfect or near-perfect representative of the system you’re trying to control or manage. You have to tweak it, move, learn; tweak it, move, learn, right? And so that’s what we know not even in economics, but in large dynamic stochastic systems.
I don’t think that’s any different with respect to macroeconomic policy. I think, as we move toward normalization, and if we believe the risks are balanced, which I do, then – and there are some risks that I’m worried about, such as some distortive effects of a low interest rate environment – then it’s time to move, and then see what happens, and then move. And so that’s what I mean by pragmatism. It’s understanding that theory, which I understand well. And as that applies to macroeconomics, it brings a more experimental flavor, I think, to the way you think, as opposed to an ideological point of view.
For me, I think that’s healthy because I know those kind of systems are inherently complex. The nonlinearity alone is complex, and then you add the stochastic nature, and there you should have a lot of humility to say we really don’t know exactly what’ll happen. That’s why we move cautiously, but move, to see what happens.
MR. DERBY: Well, in that way of thinking about things, I mean, there’s always been that axiom, you know, monetary policy works with long and variable lags.
And if you’re confronted with lots of uncertainty and you’re, you know, move, see what happens, but those see what happens are dynamics that play out over a long period of time –
MR. HARKER: They are, but then you see some of that future in things like expectations, whether they’re inflation expectations, market expectations. So you’re right, you’ll never perfectly know what’s going to happen, say, 18 months from now after you make that move, but you can get some glimpse of it with how markets respond and expectations become anchored or unanchored relative to such a move.
MR. DERBY: It seems as if there’s been – we see in the markets a lot of grumbling about the Fed communications or the guidance that the Fed has given, in that the Fed has not done with rates what the dot plot suggested it was going to do in December. Some market participants are, like, we were right, you know, we won, the Fed was wrong.
MR. HARKER: (Laughs.)
MR. DERBY: What do you think the dynamic is between financial markets and the Fed right now? Is it – is it a healthy dynamic? Or is there – is there a problem?
MR. HARKER: I don’t think there’s a problem. I do think the market is possibly underestimating the rate of normalization, but we’ll see, right?
And part of the challenge is, when it comes to communication, the dot plots are all forecasts, but people take the path of the Fed funds rate as a policy statement, not as a forecast. And we have not made that clear, right? We’re asked to forecast what we think the Fed funds rate will be. That’s a different question than saying, you know, what will the Fed funds rate be? And so that one dot plot I think causes us some problems when it comes to communication.
MR. DERBY: The December?
MR. HARKER: No, I’m just saying the path of the Fed funds rate. I think that causes us some communications challenges, because nobody says our dots for inflation or (gross domestic product) are anything other than a forecast. They take this one – and really, you think about what we’re asked: Given the path of the economy as we best know it, forecast it today, what do we think the Fed funds rate will be? But that’s not a promise that it will be that, right? And I think that’s been a challenge for us, because as things happen – as shocks, large or small, hit the economy – we have to react accordingly. We can’t stay on that predetermined path because it’s not a predetermined path.
MR. DERBY: So how do you fix it? I know (Cleveland Fed President) Loretta Mester’s talked about confidence bands. I know it’s a matter that the Communications Committee is considering. I don’t know if you’re on it. What would you like to see done differently?
MR. HARKER: So there are a lot of options. One is to add even more information with confidence bands. That’s one alternative.
The other – but it would be very difficult to do, that other central banks have done – is just get a consensus view. But we’re a large, diverse Committee. So that may work, but you know, we’d have to think about that carefully.
I mean, there are various options on how to do that.
MR. DERBY: So, but yeah, I mean, there’s nothing you particularly favor –
MR. HARKER: No, not at this point. I think we really – I need to weigh the pros and cons of that. We’re not far enough along, at least in my mind, to be able to make that decision.
MR. DERBY: And just the overall state of communications. I know there’s also been, you know, I mean, days when you’ll have four and five Fed officials speaking. The Dallas Fed had a paper that talked about maybe collectively people need to speak a little bit less and pick their – pick their spots a bit more.
MR. HARKER: Well, what do you think about that? (Laughs.)
MR. DERBY: Ah, you know, I mean, we take it as it comes. So, I mean, that’s not our place to rule in on that.
MR. HARKER: I don’t know, right? I mean, you have to be careful because the way the way the system is set up is to have – especially with the regional banks – is to have a diverse, independent view. And I think it’s – is it incumbent upon us to distill that view and to – or limit that view, or is it incumbent upon the public to distill that view, right? I mean, that’s the question, right? Should we limit what we communicate in terms of our diversity of views, or should we let the public and the media work with those diverse views? I’m more in the camp of the latter, because I think the more information we put out there it’s – the better, even if it’s not all – we’re not all saying the same thing in the same way.
MR. DERBY: OK. Well, back to the pragmatism question again. I mean, do you feel that that leaves you – and I’ll just ask this because this is often how central bankers get, you know, graded – but it does lead you to be so far more hawkish or dovish? I suppose in that you favored a rate rise in September that didn’t happen, that –
MR. HARKER: Yeah, I would tend to be because, again, I – as we discussed earlier, with the lags that we know are in such a dynamic stochastic system, I think it’s important that we take some move now and have a gradual path of normalization, as opposed to wait, wait, wait, and then have to have a steeper rise. I just think that’s prudent. And being a Philly guy, I’m more an Eagle.
MR. DERBY: Oh, yeah. (Laughter.) OK. I got to remember that one.
But on the other side of it, I mean, the Fed has undershot its inflation target for years. And the New York Fed just had a report yesterday that showed some – another little trailing off in inflation expectations. And I know they’ve – that report has shown at various points softening. And I know energy’s a big part of all of this, but you talk about the dual mandate, and one side of that mandate is still – still seems rather elusive.
MR. HARKER: But I’m seeing signs with some increase in health care inflation and others that that 2 percent target is – remember, there’s a long lag to that too, right? So I think we’re within the zone, with 1.7 percent core (personal consumption expenditures), where it is prudent to make a move sooner rather than later.
MR. DERBY: So you’re not a whites of their eyes type of –
MR. HARKER: No, because I think the lags are pretty long. And we know that, historically. So we could get behind the curve. And again, we’re talking about a 25-basis-point increase, which would leave policy still quite accommodative.
MR. DERBY: One of the things the Fed forecast changed was lowering the long-run – long-run growth rate. And I wanted to know where you – what you thought about it, because that was a – struck us as a fairly meaningful shift.
MR. HARKER: Yeah, and I lowered mine too primarily because of the neutral funds rate, right, R-star. Until we see that start to move up, and with that productivity, it’s hard to forecast that we’re going to see a robust growth. So we’ll – again, that is – we have to take that as it comes, because we don’t move R-star. Other policies do that. So we just have to accept that fact and do the best we can, given that we – in my view, as I said in the speech earlier, we don’t have a set of policies that are necessarily conductive to economic growth at this point. There are some challenges there.
MR. DERBY: Does the change in that view tell us anything about the Fed’s assessment of secular – I’m sorry – the secular stagnation argument?
MR. HARKER: The secular stagnation assumes there’s nothing that can be done to move R-star, right, by definition. I don’t believe that. I just don’t think monetary policy can move it. But I think there are things we can do to increase the potential of the economy.
MR. DERBY: So I’ve noticed that – I mean, you – that has been an emergent theme in a number of comments from Fed officials recently, about the limits of monetary policy and what could be done on the fiscal front or the other side of the equation. And why are we hearing more about that? Because you’ve spoken about it several times as well. So why –
MR. HARKER: Well, it is true, right? (Laughs.) And so I think, first, it’s true. And also it’s important that we communicate what we can’t do, right, because often people look at the Fed for solving problems that are really outside of not just our mandate, but, with the tools we have of monetary policy, our ability to effect that change.
MR. DERBY: Can you point to some examples of that?
MR. HARKER: Well, go back to the speech I made earlier, right? If we want long-term growth, it comes from population increase and productivity increase in the long run, right? If we don’t have population increase – and we know that’s been a pretty large part of what we’ve seen – we should expect slower growth. Just look at Japan as an example. There is nothing, in my view, monetary policy can really do if your economy is shrinking because the number of people you have is shrinking. You may be able to affect per capita GDP, but you can’t affect headline GDP if you – if you have a smaller population, unless you have some extraordinary productivity growth that, at least in the foreseeable future, in the planning horizon, is hard to see.
MR. DERBY: Do you think people are asking the Fed to do some of these things in part because the political process is so gummed up or paralyzed?
MR. HARKER: Yes.
MR. DERBY: So that’s part of it? And also, the extraordinary actions taken during the financial crisis, I’ve gotten the sense from some quarters, have given people the belief the Fed can do more, or is the magic thing that can fix everything, and so why not ask them to target this and target that now.
MR. HARKER: Right, right. And that is not – we can’t do that in theory nor in practice.
MR. DERBY: Well, what would you say to, say – I’m sure you’ve met with the Fed Up people, and then they’re pressing you not to raise rates because they want the –
MR. HARKER: Right.
MR. DERBY: – in their view, the recovery to spread out to everybody, and they think if you raise rates that’s not going to – that’s not going to happen.
MR. HARKER: No, I understand their frustration. I think the frustration is very real. I’ve been out and about in the community, not just meeting with Fed Up but meeting lots of people throughout the district. But the long-term solution there is back to this Agenda for Poverty and Prosperity that we have. It’s that three-legged stool. It’s jobs, skills that can – individuals can have, and the housing and the environment that they can live in to be productive. That’s going to – that’s going to move the needle. I think if – whether we change the Fed funds rate or not will have a – not anywhere near the effect that that set of changes in policy around workforce development, job creation and housing would have. And that’s why we’re really focused on that here.
MR. DERBY: Does that mean you have to interact with the political system more than otherwise would have been the case, say, in the past?
MR. HARKER: Well, I don’t know. I wasn’t here in the past, OK? (Laughs.)
MR. DERBY: Oh, well, but I mean just as – I mean, as a student of the institution.
MR. HARKER: Yeah. I think what – I think what we need to do is provide the intellectual research capability that the Fed has a lot of and train it – you know, put our lenses firmly on these issues, for two reasons. One is I think it’s the right thing to do. We’re not going to write the policy. We’re not going to decide the policy. But we can do the research that lays out the parameters of what most likely will and won’t work, right, and the costs and benefits of those.
But also, we’re not going to have the long-term growth if we don’t reach full potential. And a big part of reaching full potential in the economy is we can’t leave a lot of people behind, all right? It’s just – it’s not just going to hurt those individuals; it’s going to hurt the economy overall. That’s why I think it’s so important. If our job is maximum employment, we got to bring those people into the workforce. And I think just moving the Fed funds rate or holding it steady is not going to be very effective in doing that. It’s going to be these other issues.
MR. DERBY: Have you spoken with elected leaders –
MR. HARKER: Oh yeah.
MR. DERBY: – and got any sense that this is getting through?
MR. HARKER: Oh, they get it. Yeah, yeah.
MR. DERBY: OK.
MR. HARKER: But, you know, it’s a complicated time in our country. And again, this is not what – this is particularly one of these issues that’s not just a national issue. We tend to think of it as a national issue, but it’s community by community, city by city. You know, dealing with state leaders, city leaders, it’s really important.
You go across the river to Camden, and I spent some time over there and my mother was born in Camden. There’s a place that has a plan that they’ve put together with the administration in a bipartisan way – with the Christie administration to really bring Camden back, and do it in an inclusive way so you’re not just saying, oh, well, they’re gentrifying, but where do the gentrified go? We’re not solving the problem if the gentrified just get pushed to the edges. And so they’ve got a plan, and they’re executing that plan. And we’re doing some research there to sort of see how it plays out over time, what we can learn. That’s the kind of thing the Fed can do. We can step in and say, let’s bring our analytical capability to these issues and see what we can learn from these changes.
MR. DERBY: Well, at the national level, I got the sense from your remarks earlier today that political paralysis, or just an unwillingness of the two sides to engage, or the unwillingness of one side to engage with the other side, is a major problem for the economy right now. Did I hear that accurately?
MR. HARKER: Yeah. I mean, if – I think – you know, I think – I’ll put my citizen hat on, right, and not my Fed hat. (Laughs.)
MR. DERBY: OK.
MR. HARKER: Of course. That’s frustrating to everyone. And again, we see this in this partisan conflict index. We measure this. We know that this is elevated and it’s stayed elevated. And we know the implications of that, the results of that on economic growth: it’s not good. And so it – that’s where I think we are the Fed, with our research capability, can at least be a voice of nonpartisan, here are the facts as we know them, and you have to make use of these facts or not. It’s up to you. But this is what we know will or won’t work.
MR. DERBY: Well, in desiring to be nonpartisan, I mean, the Fed has been drug into the – or has been pulled into this election campaign in a way that I haven’t really seen before. I mean, does that – does that alarm you?
MR. HARKER: Yes. I can honestly say, in my (Federal Open Market Committee) meetings to date and my daily interactions around here, politics never enters the equation. I’ve just not seen that, right? Now, I don’t know what’s inside people’s heads, but I’ve never, ever seen it articulated in any way. People are just trying to do what they believe is the right thing with the right policy. So I think it’s unfair that we’ve been brought into this political situation because I think the strength of the Fed is that we stay independent and we stay nonpartisan. And I think the leadership of the Fed, myself included, are deeply committed to making sure that happens.
MR. DERBY: Do you think the Fed is well-suited that if it were to come under – I mean, if it were to come under strong political pressure to follow a certain policy line, would it be able to withstand that pressure?
MR. HARKER: I can’t speak for everybody else, but I could.
MR. DERBY: OK. I just figured I’d ask.
I wanted to ask you about the inflation target. There’s been some talk about raising it recently as one possible way to help address the R-star argument, among other things. So I’m curious where you stood on that matter.
MR. HARKER: Well, first, it would be good to get to 2 percent and then have that. (Laughs.) But I’m not sure increasing the inflation target will move R-star as much as just economic growth will move R-star. In which case, it would be nice if growth was that robust where we started to have the inflation target exceeded on a routine basis, and we’d have to rethink what that is. But we’re not there right now.
MR. DERBY: Right. But I thought part of the idea was that you communicate – in that you say this, that it exerts an influence.
MR. HARKER: Yeah, there are all – look, expectations are clearly a critical part of macroeconomics. That may have an effect. I’m more – and I won’t dismiss that effect. But I think the other policies will have a larger effect over time.
MR. DERBY: So you’re not looking for any changes in how the Fed approaches its inflation target right now? I know there’s another idea of, like, ending the bygones policy.
MR. HARKER: I don’t think right now. Until we get past where we are now towards something that one may consider more normal, I think it’s – then it’s time to revisit that.
MR. DERBY: OK. And I know we’ve talked a lot about – or just you’ve confronted these questions before – but just the Fed being ready or having tools in case it confronts another economic downturn.
MR. HARKER: Yeah. I mean, I – that’s another reason I am supportive of a slow but consistent path toward normalization, so we can get further and further away from zero. I think there are risks of hanging around zero too long. And if the economy can withstand it, I think it’s appropriate to move.
MR. DERBY: What would you say to people that say the entire reason why the stock market is at the levels that it’s at is because of near-zero rates and Fed actions, and –
MR. HARKER: Yeah, I’m always skeptical of somebody who says that the sole reason – the only reason is this. I think it is a contributing factor. Is it the only factor? No. But I do believe it’s a contributing factor. And I say that going back to my previous life as a corporate director. Again, you are looking at shareholder value, and you’re looking at shareholder value and how to enhance it. Well, in the long run, it is investing in new businesses, investing in new plant and equipment.
But you also can return value to the shareholder through dividends or stock buybacks. And if the debt is that cheap, it’s one of the things that your – one of the arrows in your quiver that you’re going to use. When debt is that cheap, you’re going to make that switch from equity to debt. And I think there is some truth in the fact that the equities markets reflect those individual decisions by companies that are perfectly rational for those companies to do in this low-rate environment.
MR. DERBY: Do you worry, though, that raising rates, as it starts to affect that calculus, starts to deflate or cause the stock market to sell off, and then that’s a negative input for confidence and it just causes things to come from that?
MR. HARKER: Not if we do it – not if we do it cautiously and pace the rate of normalization. If we have to do it quickly, I’d worry about that. But that’s why I don’t want to have a wait and then rapid rise later policy.
MR. DERBY: And do you believe – I mean, it sounds like from the meeting minutes people are coming around to there’s going to be an action relatively soon.
MR. HARKER: Yeah, again, I can’t speak for the Committee. But for me, I would like to see that sooner rather than later.
MR. DERBY: Take another step back and talk about some of the reform proposals that have been directed towards the Fed.
MR. HARKER: Sure.
MR. DERBY: One of the ideas – we’ll just go down them by the list – this will actually be (Dartmouth College economics professor) Andy Levin’s list in a way, but just because it kind of pulled together a lot of different things. But the quasi-private status of the regional Federal Reserve banks, I mean, that has been long something that has – outside critics have criticized the Fed for. You know, you hear arguments the Fed is just doing the work of the bankers that own it. If the Fed were to be made – regional Fed banks were to be made fully part of government, would it help address that criticism?
MR. HARKER: I don’t think so, because I – we’ll start with the fact that I don’t think the bankers – I can only speak for myself – influence my policy decisions, other than the information they give me on what’s happening in their communities.
And so one of the reform proposals is to remove bankers from the board, right? That would be part of this proposal. And I think that’s a mistake, because if I think about my board, we meet every 14 days, they vote on the discount rate, and I get information from them about what is going on in their communities. And that information, to me, is very important because data, by definition, is backward looking, right? You can only have data about what happened. They give me information about, for example, one banker was involved with a health care institution in his community. Nurses were getting a 9 percent raise and they were getting – teeing up for a possible other increase in their wages because they couldn’t find nurses. That’s actually helpful information. As we start to tease out the picture of where we’re seeing wage pressure, OK, that’s only one anecdote and you have to be careful of solo – you know, caution about anecdotes, but it still – it gives you some sense of the right questions to ask, right?
Similarly, asking the bankers and others on the board what they see with respect to business investment. We have a lot of data on that, but what are they seeing on the ground? What are people doing and not doing? And again, in our case, all the bankers are community bankers. They’re not (Large Institution Supervision Coordinating Committee) institutions. They’re institutions that are serving their local communities, and they’re part of the fabric of those local communities. Those voices are really important to me, and I’d hate to lose those.
MR. DERBY: You can’t have them on an advisory council and meet with them –
MR. HARKER: You could, but not every 14 days.
MR. DERBY: OK.
MR. HARKER: You’re not going to have any advisory council – (laughs) – I mean, we have a great advisory council, our Economic Community Advisory Council, chaired by Madeline Bell, who’s the head of Children’s Hospital here, one of the leading if not the leading children’s hospital in the world. But again, we meet on a regular basis, but not that frequently. And so I worry about losing information in that process.
MR. DERBY: OK. But on the matter of Fed ownership, I mean, you don’t see that – any conflicts coming from that structure?
MR. HARKER: It’s never affected – again, I can only – it’s never affected anything with respect to our policy stance – my policy stance.
MR. DERBY: And how do you ensure that, say, board members don’t get information about the policy outlook that other people – like, if it’s not being distributed, you know, broadly?
MR. HARKER: Yeah, I mean, they get the same economic update that we would give to any group as we run around the district and talk about – you know, our economists talking about issues. They don’t get any proprietary information. Everything we present to them, at least here in Philly, is publicly disclosed information.
MR. DERBY: There was a change that the New York Fed had made on its – how it handled the –
(Break.)
MR. DERBY: There we go. The New York Fed had made a change in how it briefed, or made – the president no longer gives a recommendation on what the discount rate should be, so that whatever the board votes from is entirely self – it comes from them now. And that way they don’t have any – they can’t draw an inference from what the president – say, President Dudley – tells them. Do you have that same policy here?
MR. HARKER: No. And I don’t get the sense, though – my board is quite independent. And as a director, I was quite independent. So I’m not sure that it has that kind of influence, at least in Philadelphia. I can’t speak for any other bank.
MR. DERBY: So you – just to be clear, I mean, you do it the traditional – you make a recommendation to them based on –
MR. HARKER: And the board is quite independent in their perspective on that.
MR. DERBY: OK. Actually, that is a question. I mean, from your – what’s different from – what’s changed in your perspectives from being on the board to being a president? What do you know now about how this all works that you didn’t know then?
MR. HARKER: I know a lot. (Laughter.)
So I think the biggest issue is outside of monetary policy. It’s just the complexity of the Federal Reserve system and everything that we do, right? When you sit in a board room, you have some sense of that, but you don’t get a deep dive in everything we’re doing in the community. And by definition, the board members have no access into supervisory information, right? Because we do – there is a real strict wall of separation there, other than anything that’s public information. So obviously, on this side, as the supervisors, as the regulators, I have a lot more information now than I ever had as a board member.
MR. DERBY: So it’s mostly an informational difference?
MR. HARKER: Yeah.
MR. DERBY: I think what people might find interesting: How much of your time do you spend on actual economic and monetary policy thinking and working, compared to the other demands of the job?
MR. HARKER: So, of course, it goes in cycles, right. There’s, I think, for me, eight times a year (inaudible) the FOMC. Then we have a conversation with the team here after the FOMC, just a sort of after-action report of, you know, what’s happening. I would say in any given cycle of eight times a year. So think of that roughly as six weeks; so a little more than a third. We may even be bumping up to half of that is spent on monetary-policy issues. Another big chunk of that is spent on regional development issues and community development issues, which I think feed into that view. And then there’s the day-to-day running a bank.
MR. DERBY: Yeah. I mean, it’s a large organization with a lot of stuff to do in services and –
MR. HARKER: Right. Right, right.
MR. DERBY: Yeah, interesting.
Back on the reform front, one thing we didn’t talk about was diversity. And that is now coming even more into the fore with what’s happening down in Atlanta with the congressman writing about, you know, their hopes for the pick down there. Can the Fed – can and should the Fed do better in terms of diversity, especially at its top leadership levels, again, when it comes to governors and bank presidents?
MR. HARKER: Yes.
MR. DERBY: OK.
MR. HARKER: So I think about Philadelphia. We’ve had a 20 percent increase in the diversity of our top leadership team here, and we’ve – and if I think about the board, we’ve tried to increase diversity there both in terms of ethnicity and gender. Our Economic Community Advisory Council, which gives us an insight into what’s happening in communities, but also an opportunity to engage people possibly being board members, that is quite diverse. Sixty percent of those members are either women, minorities, or both, because there’s overlap.
So I think we’re making progress, and I think with the staff as a whole. But there is an issue at the top, and as you mentioned, at the senior leadership within at least – I can only speak for this bank. And there’s a matter of working hard to bring people – bring them into the Fed system, get them the experiences they need to grow in leadership in the Fed, and to be prepared for those next steps. I think that’s an area I’m very committed to, because it starts with recruiting a diverse workforce here, or, in the case of directors, diverse directors, and having sort of feeder systems for that, whether it’s inside the bank and the system or outside that you could then draw from.
MR. DERBY: Well, I’ve heard the case made one of the problems is because the academic profession is tilted in the way that it is that academic economists have been historically tilted towards white men, and that’s just – that is the reality of who is in the profession. And so, therefore, as you’re looking for people to move up through it, it’s – that creates a –
MR. HARKER: I mean, as a former university president, it’s not just economics; (science, technology, engineering and mathematics) disciplines generally. That’s a problem. I think, in terms of gender, that’s starting to change in those disciplines. But it’s still a challenge for underrepresented groups. So I think that is a challenge.
But we need to then therefore look for leadership not necessarily out of that channel, right, and look for others, whether it’s coming from experience in the financial-services industry or other parts of academia or other industries altogether. I think we need to start broadening our thinking about that if we’re going to really change the nature of the leadership of the Federal Reserve. And I do think it’s important to do. I mean, we’re very committed – I’m very committed to that here. We’re making some progress, but we need to keep pushing.
MR. DERBY: Has the lack of diversity had any policy implications so far?
MR. HARKER: Well, in addition to diversity of ethnicity, gender, et cetera, it’s also important to have diversity of thought. And so I am concerned about avoiding group-think. So that, I think, has more policy implications than other forms of diversity, although I do think we need to have appropriate and important understanding of low-, moderate-income communities and what they’re facing. I think that is important. And that’s why we have really enhanced our efforts here in our community development, in this agenda, to really get a deeper, deeper understanding of what’s going on there, because that has to inform our policy as well. And so the leadership has to be informed by that. They don’t necessarily have to come from that. But they could, right? They potentially could.
MR. DERBY: Do you think the Philadelphia Fed is fixed to be a leader on, say, understanding the plight of low and –
MR. HARKER: I hope so. Yeah, I hope so, for two reasons. One, I think we have the talent here to do that. And second, it’s important to this district. If we’re going to serve the district, which is part of our charge, we have challenges in this district. We have a lot of opportunity, too, in Philadelphia, but we’ve got some challenges.
MR. DERBY: OK. Well, I often do this towards the end of interviews sometimes, but to ask if, I mean, if there is any issue or thing that you would like to see people talk about or point that you feel that you’ve been trying to make that might not be getting through. Kind of an open-ended question there, but I mean, is there something you think people need to understand about the Fed that they’re – it’s just not getting through? Is there anything like that?
MR. HARKER: I’d go back to our earlier conversation. I do think that people don’t quite understand the limits of what monetary policy can do, and therefore what the Fed can do. And we’re – we create the environment, the platform for the economy to grow, but we’re not going to drive that growth. As I said earlier in the Q&A after the speech, I think people – we don’t have the secret sauce all by ourselves that’s going to make the economy grow. It’s just not the way it works. And I think people don’t necessarily understand that. And I’m worried about that because I think we’re being asked to do more than we’re capable of.
Source
Between the Lines: Charter Schools, A Better Education for Some at a Cost to Others
Five students are suing the state for a better education — for some. In September, five anonymous students...
Five students are suing the state for a better education — for some.
In September, five anonymous students filed a suit against the state in Suffolk County Superior Court alleging the cap on the number of charter schools in Massachusetts unfairly denies them their right to a quality education. The students had entered charter lotteries, but failed to win coveted spots in one of the public-ish schools. Instead, the students say, they were assigned to attend schools in their home districts that had been deemed “underperforming” by the state.
Since No Child Left Behind, school reform has been more concerned with helping some children find ways out of the traditional public school system than improving education for everyone. Charter schools are a symptom of this escapist philosophy, which is unfortunate because the idea of a charter school education is a good one.
Typically founded by nonprofits and members of the community, charter schools often concentrate education around one subject. Locally, these concentrations include the arts, social justice, and Mandarin. Students enroll in charters through a blind lottery that anyone can enter. Placing students in schools that encourage their passions is excellent education. And it produces some positive results. For example, in 2013, Credo, an independent education research firm, analyzed the impact charter schools have had on Massachusetts. In math and reading, researchers found that charter school students perform better in the subjects compared to those in traditional public schools.
The problem with charter schools is the education provided comes at the cost of traditional public schools. Charter schools are publicly funded, but work independently of a hometown district. Last year in Massachusetts, participating school districts paid charter schools $369.7 million to educate students. Charters receive per-student fees from sending districts — money that would otherwise stay in the home school’s till. Children fleeing an underperforming school district take money with them that is needed to improve the local education system.
I’m not proposing students be forced to attend failing schools. A student should have the choice to attend the school that best fits her educational needs. I am asking the state’s politicians to take a hard look at how charters are managed, funded, and how students are enrolled – because the current system is inadequate. Earlier this month, Gov. Charlie Baker proposed a bill that would increase the number of charter schools in the state. The bill would permit 12 new or expanded charter schools each year in districts performing in the bottom 25 percent on standardized tests. Massachusetts already has 81 charter schools with a waiting list of 37,000 students. A bill to expand the cap on charter schools in the state passed the House last year, but floundered in the Senate.
Here’s what needs to happen with charters:
Improve special education and non-native English speaker recruitment: While charters typically serve about the same number of low-income students — and more students of color — as traditional public school systems, they enroll far fewer non-native English speakers and students with special education needs. The Credo audit found that in traditional Massachusetts public schools that send children to charters, 17 percent of students received special education services, whereas in charter schools this population made up 12 percent of the student body. Traditional public schools had 10 percent English language learners in the student body, while charters had 6 percent.
Submit to School Committee authority: Charters don’t play by the same rules as traditional public schools. The schools aren’t subject to the authority of an elected school committee and have a legal pass around some of the state’s educational and special education requirements.
There’s good reason for more oversight. Private management of charter schools. A new report claims more than $200 million in fraud and wasted taxpayer funds has been lost to the charter school sector (“The Tip of the Iceberg: Charter School Vulnerabilities To Waste, Fraud, And Abuse” by Alliance to Reclaim Our Schools and the Center for Popular Democracy). It’s hard to say whether this same kind of scandal could occur in Massachusetts. Charter schools need to, at the very least, be subject to more public scrutiny and submit to the budgeting and policy authority of a local, elected school committee.
Analyze funding strategy: Charter schools should not be succeeding at the cost of the education of students in underperforming districts. Something must be done that will allow students to pick the education that is best for them without penalizing struggling schools.
The student plantiffs suing for their right to attend charter schools say the state charter cap unfairly denies their right to a quality education, but that right cannot come at the cost of the rest of Massachusetts’ students.•
Source: Valley Advocate
7 days ago
7 days ago